The Natural History of Child Signals of Need in Utila, Honduras: An Exploratory Study

Authors
Affiliations

Michael R. Gaffney

Washington State University

Jessica K. Hlay

Boston University

Izabel Rodriguez

Kristen L. Syme

Leiden University

Steven A. Arnocky

Nipissing University

Aaron D. Blackwell

Washington State University

Carolyn R. Hodges-Simeon

Boston University

Edward H. Hagen

Washington State University

1 Abstract

To gain support, children use signals to communicate their needs and wants to parents. Infant signals of need, particularly infant cries, have been extensively studied in diverse populations. However, the full range of potential child signals of need, which extend beyond cries, has rarely been investigated in a single study of children of all ages. To help fill this gap, we collected mother and other primary caregiver reports of three common types of child signaling from 140 families with 263 children on Utila, a small island off the coast of Honduras. In exploratory analyses, we found that child signaling was common in both sexes and across all ages, although it decreased with age and neighborhood quality and increased with the frequency of conflict between children and caretakers. Consistent with signaling theory, children who were sad more frequently were perceived as needier within the household and were more likely to receive investment. Caregivers were less likely to respond positively in situations of family conflict or child transgressions, and more likely for injuries and illness. Our results suggest that evolutionary theories of signaling can help explain patterns of child sadness, crying, and temper tantrums.

2 Introduction

Compared to chimpanzee mothers, human mothers in hunter-gatherer societies have shorter interbirth intervals and produce offspring that require many more years of parental care (Davison and Gurven 2021; Davison and Gurven 2022). Unlike chimpanzee offspring, human offspring in ancestral populations therefore often grew up with multiple older and/or younger siblings who were potential competitors for parental investment and yet who could also provide (or require) allocare (Helfrecht and Meehan 2016; Lawson and Borgerhoff Mulder 2016; Hagen and Barrett 2009). Juveniles in humans, unlike chimps, therefore evolved in families with multiple siblings simultaneously dependent on parents and others for essential care, likely intensifying selection for credible signals of need (Leonard et al. 2000; Harper 1986; Neuenschwander et al. 2003).

Although infant signals of need, particularly infant cries, have been extensively studied in many populations (Barr et al. 1991; Fouts, Hewlett, and Lamb 2005; Konner 1974; Kruger and Konner 2010; Kushnick 2006; Meehan, Hagen, and Hewlett 2017; Müller 2021; Tronick, Morelli, and Winn 1987), the full range of potential child signals of need, which likely extend beyond cries, has never been investigated in children of all ages. In particular, how and when older children signal need has rarely been investigated (for one exception, see Syme and Hagen 2023). The aim of this study was to help fill these gaps by investigating three common types of signals of need in children and adolescents.

2.1 Conflicts of interest within the family

Although the fitness prospects of children and their familial caretakers are largely intertwined, evolutionary theory predicts that disagreements about the amount of investment from parents and other close kin will be ubiquitous (Fouts, Hewlett, and Lamb 2005; Godfray 1995; Godfray and Parker 1992; Trivers 1974; Bossan, Hammerstein, and Koehncke 2013) because each child shares more genes with themselves (100%) than (through recent common descent) with their full siblings (50% on average), half-siblings (25% on average), and stepsiblings (0%). Due to this asymmetry, children are often expected to attempt to elicit more investment from parents than is optimal from the perspective of the parent, while parents are expected to attempt to invest less than is optimal for each child in order to invest in their other children, whom parents are expected to value identically, all else being equal (Trivers 1974; Bossan, Hammerstein, and Koehncke 2013).

For the same reason, siblings have both confluences and conflicts of interest with one another, with each expected to prefer more resources for himself or herself than others. Sibling competition is evident across taxa and can range from relatively benign forms like strong begging competition in chicks (Caro, West, and Griffin 2016) to siblicide in birds, mammals, and sharks (Salmon and Hehman 2014). In humans, sibling competition is largely estimated by counts of siblings, and large numbers of siblings have been associated with decreased growth (Hadley et al. 2011; Hagen, Barrett, and Price 2006; Salmon and Hehman 2014), survival (Lawson, Alvergne, and Gibson 2012; Meij et al. 2009; Strassmann 2011), and reproductive success (Gibson and Gurmu 2011; Mace 1996) in multiple populations, highlighting the likely significance of sibling competition for resources, even if this does not always manifest with behavioral conflict (Bateson 1994).

Whereas parent-offspring conflict and sibling competition are likely ubiquitous, the resources being contested will vary across human groups. In relatively egalitarian and food constrained populations, conflict over resources is likely to be centered on food, which probably explains the negative impacts siblings have on child age-specific heights and weights among the Shuar of Ecuador (Hagen and Barrett 2009), although similar effects have also been found in industrialized populations (Lawson and Mace 2008). In societies with greater inequality, competition is more likely to be over wealth, as is the case with older brothers in pastoralist communities like the Gabbra and Arsi Oromo limiting the marriage prospects of laterborn sons (Gibson and Gurmu 2011; Mace 1996). Compared to large-scale investments like bride price or inheritance, little is understood about smaller transfers of wealth to younger children despite the potential importance of such transfers to 1) facilitate the development of embodied capital outside of growth and fat reserves or 2) help children succeed in their peer groups.

2.2 Cooperation within the family

Humans are a uniquely interdependent species among the living primates (Tomasello et al. 2012) in that both sexes’ fitness prospects depend greatly on a network of close kin and other social allies (Apicella and Silk 2019; Syme and Balliet 2024). This need for others is most intense with children, who are born highly altricial and require many years of investment to develop to the point where they can obtain enough food to survive on their own and develop the social skills needed to succeed in their communities (Kaplan, Hooper, and Gurven 2009; Rosenberg 2021; Schniter et al. 2015). Much of this investment comes from mothers and fathers (Kramer and Veile 2018). However, grandparents, aunts, uncles, and non-relatives also provide significant investment in children in many societies (Kramer and Veile 2018; Sear and Mace 2008), which was likely favored due to a combination of inclusive fitness benefits, reciprocity, and reputation management (Gurven et al. 2000; Schniter et al. 2023). Children also often serve as alloparents, helping to raise their younger siblings via direct care, food collection and preparation, and other family tasks (Hrdy 2009; Meehan 2009; Sear and Mace 2008) despite still requiring substantial amounts of investment themselves (Kramer 2018).

Children’s potential to invest in their families can also cause conflicts with their parents. Older children can provide greater allocare, but might prefer to spend their time investing in romantic or other social relationships, or learning valuable skills, whereas parents might prefer them to care for their siblings, acquire or prepare food, or complete other household chores (Lowe 2003; Syme and Hagen 2023). Conflicts of interest over investment in the family can even involve adult children who are starting to have their own children (Kushnick 2023; Emlen 1995). Parents can potentially benefit from delaying the reproductive careers of certain offspring to gain more allocare for their other children (Flinn 1989; Emlen and Wrege 1992) or speeding up a child’s departure from the household to provide more parental investment to other children (Kushnick 2023).

2.3 Signals of needs and wants

In order to elicit more support, children often use signals of needs and wants. Across the tree of life, signals evolve to reveal agents’ private information to other agents when doing so benefits both the signaler and the receiver (Caro, West, and Griffin 2016; Maynard-Smith and Harper 2004; Preuschoft and Schaik 2000; Setchell and Jean Wickings 2005; Zahavi 1975). Children often have needs and wants, where needs involve avoiding potential fitness costs, such as poor nutrition, injuries, or threats to status, and wants involve acquiring potential fitness benefits, such as highly nutritious foods and valuable artifacts. Needs and wants (hereafter needs) are often not apparent to caregivers, i.e., they are private information, and hence children must signal them to receive help. Signals differ from cues in that signals were favored by natural selection due to their ability to alter the behavior or perceptions of others in ways that benefit the signaler, on average, whereas cues are information organisms use to influence their behavior or physiological state that did not evolve for communicative effect (Maynard Smith and Harper 1995). Crying when injured is likely a signal of need, for instance, whereas bleeding would be a cue of need.

When the fitness interests of signalers and receivers are aligned, i.e., there are no conflicts of interest, child signals of need are expected to be what Maynard Smith and Harper (1995) refer to as “minimal signals,” signals whose cost is no greater than that needed to transmit the information effectively. In other words, although minimal signals might involve some cost (e.g., energy for a loud scream), they do not require any additional mechanism to enforce honesty.

When conflicts of interest over investment exist, however, there may be much to gain from deception (e.g., crying despite the lack of need) so that one could receive the benefits that come from being seen as needy (Zahavi 1993). Unchecked, deceptive signals could result in receivers ignoring all signals. Credible signals can nevertheless evolve and be maintained in multiple ways, such as when signals cannot be faked (i.e., indexical signals). Credible signals can also evolve when the benefits of sending a signal outweigh the costs for individuals with the underlying quality or state, but otherwise the costs outweigh the benefits (Spence 1973; Zahavi 1975; Chisausky et al. 2023). Such signals are often termed “costly,” although what is costly is deception, not necessarily signaling per se (for discussion, see Chisausky et al. 2023).1

In the context of child signals of need, a child has access to information about their internal state, which is unavailable to others, that allows them to estimate their valuation of additional investment. When there are conflicts of interest between children and their caregivers, children might need to use signals whose costs outweigh the benefits of additional care for those not in need, e.g., because increased caregiver investment is less valuable to them and/or the opportunity costs of signaling are higher, but would result in a net benefit to those with genuine needs. In doing so, the child reveals their resource valuation to potential caretakers who may be skeptical of the child’s claims. With the information revealed by the signal, caretakers should generally be more likely to provide additional support due to their fitness interest in the child’s wellbeing.

However, even credible signals of need might not result in a beneficial response because belief in a child’s need is not the only factor determining the form and amount of support given by caregivers. Instead, caregivers are expected to weigh the costs and benefits of support, which would take into account the reproductive value of current and future offspring, against other options (Daly and Wilson 1987, 1983), with selection favoring the allocation of parental investment to current and future offspring that equalizes marginal fitness returns to the parent (Clutton-Brock 1991; Daly and Wilson 1983, 1983; Dawkins 1976; Hagen 1999; Beaulieu and Bugental 2008; Frankenhuis and Amir 2022).

Additionally, a parent may also decide against investing in a child, despite deeming that investment worthwhile, if the time is not right (e.g., if a mother preferred to breastfeed during rest rather than when foraging). When this is the case, outward conflicts might not reflect genuine conflicts of interest and instead involve parents teaching children ways to behave that benefit them both (Altmann 1980). Finally, caregivers often have better information about the costs and benefits of various items and actions, and therefore can make more beneficial decisions for a child than the child can herself (e.g., preventing a child from playing with matches).

2.3.1 Sadness

Sadness is an internal affective state that also has signaling functions in the form of facial expressions and other behavioral manifestations. It is generally thought to arise from loss (Horwitz, Wakefield, and Lorenzo-Luaces 2017; Levenson 1999; Smith and Lazarus 1993), especially when one has little power to reverse or mitigate the loss without help (Emanuel and Eldar 2023; Gunderson et al. 2021). Sadness and low mood, like other forms of psychological pain, probably evolved to motivate victims of adversity to shift their attention to the causes of adversity to mitigate its negative fitness consequences and to learn to solve or avoid similar events in the future (Andrews and Thomson 2009; Nesse 1990; Thornhill and Thornhill 1989). Low mood, for example, is often thought to be adaptive in situations when activity is dangerous or unlikely to result in benefits, with anhedonia, pessimism, and fatigue all helping reduce behavior that may not be worth the costs or that may cause additional problems (Nesse 2019; Nettle 2009; Trimmer et al. 2015). It may also encourage the reappraisal of one’s circumstances after new information comes to light that one’s current strategy is not working (Nesse and Ellsworth 2009).

Through the reduction in behavior and attention in one’s usual interests that can accompany sadness and low-mood (Nettle 2009), one’s relatives and other social partners would likely gain some indication, in the form of cues, that the sad individual was experiencing adversity and could benefit from increased support. In addition to this cue-based information, sadness also results in facial expressions and crying, both of which probably evolved to signal need (Balsters et al. 2013; Bowlby 1980; Reed and DeScioli 2017; Darwin 1872). Such expressions seem to be important to conveying this information as is seen by the skeptical responses to those who cannot produce certain elements of facial expressions like tear production (Hasson 2009; Nesse 2019) or certain facial movements (Bogart, Tickle-Degnen, and Joffe 2012; Bogart and Matsumoto 2010). We conceptualize infrequent and transient sadness signals as minimal signals of need (per Maynard Smith and Harper 1995). Frequent or prolonged sadness, however, is likely a form of withdrawal or depression, both of which might be effective costly signals of need when there are conflicts between the child and their caregivers (for theory and evidence, see Gaffney et al. 2022; Syme and Hagen 2023).

2.3.2 Crying

Crying is the most studied way children signal need. Crying is a human universal (Gracanin, Bylsma, and Vingerhoets 2018) with few suspected non-signaling functions outside of the role vocal cries might play in the development of vocalization (Wells 2003) and the functions tears have in cleaning, protecting, and lubricating the eye (Murube 2009; Sznycer, Gracanin, and Lieberman 2023). Hunger, pain, anger, fear, and separation are all common causes of crying (Vingerhoets 2013; Wells 2003), although tear production also often happens with joyful events (Sznycer, Gracanin, and Lieberman 2023; Vingerhoets 2013; Zickfeld et al. 2020).

Infant cries increase amounts of care, resources, and attention infants receive, as well as increase their proximity to parents (Lin and McFatter 2012). For example, Karo Batak infants who cried more were breastfed more, and the length of crying bouts predicted the time mothers breastfed (Kushnick 2006). Similarly, !Kung San mothers frequently respond to crying infants by providing comfort and breastfeeding access, with comforting behaviors being far more common than behaviors restricting infants (Kruger and Konner 2010). Although Kruger and Konner (2010) found mothers were the most common responders, siblings, fathers, and other adults frequently stepped in so that 88% of crying bouts were responded to, with most of the cries ignored lasting under ten seconds. Similar responsiveness has also been reported among the Aka (Hewlett et al. 1998), the Mbendjele (Chaudhary, Salali, and Swanepoel 2024), the Efe (Tronick, Morelli, and Winn 1987), and the Aché, among whom young children have been described as “win[ning] most conflicts with parents simply by crying and whining” (Kaplan and Dove 1987). Studies examining the potential for long-term benefits are rare and difficult to achieve. However, during a time of high infant mortality in a sample of 13 Massai infants, those with easy temperaments were more likely to die (5/7) than those with difficult temperaments (1/6), an outcome that is consistent with signals eliciting beneficial treatment (de Vries 1987).

Crying does not always succeed in eliciting benefits, however. Compared to the previously mentioned groups, the Ngandu (Hewlett et al. 1998) and the Hadza (Blurton Jones 1993) have been found to be more likely to ignore the cries of infants and young children, and concerns that being too responsive will spoil children are reasonably common in some Western populations (Barnett et al. 2010; Burchinal, Skinner, and Reznick 2010; Chaudhary, Salali, and Swanepoel 2024; Frankenhuis and Amir 2022; Maute and Perren 2018). Crying can also lead to negative responses beyond being ignored (Barr 1990; Soltis 2004; Zeifman and St James-Roberts 2017). It has been found to increase parental distress, the likelihood of maternal depression, and the child’s risk of maltreatment (Frodi 1985; Fujiwara et al. 2011; Howard et al. 2006; Lin and McFatter 2012; Soltis 2004). For example, in a sample of 3,259 Dutch parents with infants under 6 months old, 5.6% self-reported smothering, slapping, or shaking their babies in response to their crying, outcomes that were more likely among parents who were single, unemployed, or deemed their infant’s crying to be excessive (Reijneveld et al. 2004). Excessive infant crying, i.e., colic, has also been found to be a risk factor for multiple negative outcomes (Zeevenhooven et al. 2018), including abuse, shaken baby syndrome (Kurth et al. 2011), and earlier cessation of breastfeeding (Howard et al. 2006).

Although it is widely accepted that crying is a signal, there is no consensus on if or when it should be conceptualized as a minimal signal, a costly signal, an indexical signal, or a deceptive (manipulative) signal. Contact calls between parents and offspring have evolved in numerous species, so cries might simply be a means for infants to elicit attention from caregivers (Mehr et al. 2021), which would be a type of minimal signal. Demonstrating vigor and health early in life was likely vital for much of our evolutionary history due to the risk of neglect or infanticide experienced by children with poor survival prospects (Daly and Wilson 1984; Soltis 2004). As crying comes with physiological costs (Rao et al. 1997; Thureen et al. 1998), it could serve as a credible signal of vigor if these costs are too high for unhealthy infants to bear (Furlow 1997; Lummaa 1998; Soltis 2004; Wells 2003). Children with severe medical conditions also produce acoustically distinct cries, suggesting that some elements of crying are indexical (Soltis 2004). Alternatively, crying might impose costs on caregivers by, e.g., attracting predators or interfering with important activities, motivating caregivers to invest more to stop the crying (so-called blackmail or bargaining models, Zahavi 1977; Lummaa 1998; Eshel and Feldman 1991; Bergstrom and Bergstrom 1999; Kennedy and Radford 2021).

For older children, the relatively insignificant energetic costs of crying might not be enough to ensure it is a credible signal when there are conflicts of interest. For this reason, crying among older children might be more similar to adult crying, which can increase support and empathy but sometimes comes with social costs (Cornelius and Labott 2001; Cretser et al. 1982; Hendriks and Vingerhoets 2006; Jesser 1989; Vingerhoets, Ven, and Velden 2016; Glasberg and Aboud 1981, 1982; Zeman and Garber 1996). Such costs could be a means by which crying can still be a credible signal of need if they dissuade potential fakers from making the signal when there are conflicts of interest (Sznycer, Gracanin, and Lieberman 2023).

2.3.3 Temper tantrums

Temper tantrums may also be the result of adaptive strategies by which children can elicit more support from parents (Koch 2003). They are common in children from 18 months to 4 years old (Potegal and Davidson 2003) but are also exhibited by older children, albeit with decreased frequency (Macfarlane, Allen, and Honzik 1954; Barbarin 1999; Ward 1970; Österman and Björkqvist 2010; Goodenough 1931; Bhatia et al. 1990). Temper tantrums vary in their severity and include behaviors ranging from crying, shrieking, and screaming to violent bodily movements, aggression, and self-harm (Potegal and Davidson 2003). Similar behaviors are also seen in other young animals, often surrounding feeding or weaning conflict (Altmann 1980; Goodall 1986; Schaller 1964). Tantrums have been reported in many societies with different forms of subsistence systems, political organization, and norms surrounding anger and parenting (Albino and Thompson 1956; Bani Salameh et al. 2021; Fouts, Hewlett, and Lamb 2005; Henderson 1966; Hilger 1957; Konner 1974; Ward 1970; Johnson 2003; Bhatia et al. 1990; Myers 1988; Du Bois, Kardiner, and Oberholzer 1944), suggesting they might be a human universal (Potegal 2019). As with the other proposed signals of need, they are capable of eliciting a wide range of responses, including pro-child responses (e.g., parents giving in to a child’s wishes), neutral responses (e.g., parents ignoring the child, Hilger 1957; Konner 1974; Johnson 2003), and negative responses like abuse (Schmitt 1987).

Temper tantrums are closely linked to anger (Potegal and Davidson 2003), suggesting conflict with caregivers, and have high costs even when the tantrum is brief. Thus, temper tantrums might be useful when there are substantial and immediate gains to be had from a credible signal of need. This distinguishes them from sadness, and even crying, which are often unrelated to conflicts and have low costs when short-lived.

The costs of temper tantrums could be energetic or come from the risk or implication of self-harm (Lummaa 1998). For example, Utilian mothers reported in focus groups that some temper tantrums involved children banging their heads on things when they do not get what they want, behaviors that have been reported in other populations (Belden, Thomson, and Luby 2008; Burrows and Spiro 1953; Daniels, Mandleco, and Luthy 2012; Dennis 1940; Van den akker, Hoffenaar, and Overbeek 2022). Similarly, young chimpanzees have been observed to beat their heads on the ground when refused access to breast milk (Goodall 1986), and American white pelican chicks have been found to throw themselves on the ground, flail violently, and bite at their own wings when begging for food (Schaller 1964). Such behaviors could credibly signal need if the benefits of care for those who are truly in need outweigh the signal costs, whereas for those who are not in need, the benefits of care do not outweigh the signal costs, thus deterring deceptive signaling (Hagen, Watson, and Hammerstein 2008).

Alternatively, because tantrums impose direct costs on caretakers by interfering with important tasks (Altmann 1980) like finding or preparing food or taking care of other children, they might be more akin to a strategy to coerce caretakers into providing more support.

2.4 Study Aims

This study aimed to establish the natural history of child signaling in Utila, Honduras, by measuring various indices of adversity, children’s conflicts with caregivers, the frequencies of three common child signals of need, and various types of caregiver responses. From these, we used signaling theory to explore 1) the causes of child signals of need, 2) how and why signal costs might vary, 3) how caregivers respond to indications of child need, 4) how signaling behavior changes with age and sex, 5) and if there were differences in child signaling and parental responses in two subpopulations that face different levels of social and economic adversity.

More specifically, we hypothesized that children have evolved strategies to tailor their signals of need to 1) their valuation of a given resource, 2) the presence of existing information about a child’s needs and wants (i.e., potential to benefit from a resource) and 3) the extent of conflicts of interest with caretakers, which should influence the decision to use minimal signals or signals whose costs would deter deception. Such strategies can lead to some combination of verbal requests for more support and facial sadness, which we consider to be minimal signals, or withdrawal, temper tantrums and self-harm, which we consider “costly” signals. Crying might be considered a “minimal” signal in some circumstances, such as when a child needs a loud auditory signal to attract attention on a noisy playground, but a “costly” signal in others, such as lengthy bouts that incur physiological costs in infants signaling vigor and social costs in older children signaling need. Similarly, infrequent sadness would be a minimal signal, but frequent sadness might be better conceptualized as costly withdrawal or depression.

A major challenge when studying signals of need is the fact that such signaling is expected to 1) be more common in times when individuals can benefit from increased investment (e.g., when they are facing major adversity or when a fitness-relevant opportunity arises) and 2) result in benefits to the signaler on average. This hypothesized causal, bi-directional relationship between investment and signaling makes it difficult to isolate the effects of signaling behavior on investment in children, especially given the lack of prior studies on signaling by older children in low-income settings. For this reason, all analyses of these unique data were exploratory and meant to lay the foundation for future studies of child signaling.

3 Methods

3.1 Study population

This study of children aged 5-20 and their parents and other primary caretakers was conducted in Utila, Honduras, one of the country’s small Bay Islands in the Western Caribbean. Participants in the study were sampled from two populations that face different levels of economic and social adversity: 1) a long-standing English-speaking community primarily comprising descendants of British immigrants who arrived on the island in the 1800’s, and 2) a more recent community of Spanish-speakers, mostly from mainland Honduras. Compared to the former, the latter are more likely to live in crowded and suboptimal conditions, face active discrimination and increased stress (Garcia, Gurven, and Blackwell 2017), and experience economic uncertainty due the predominance of low paying, seasonal jobs primarily related to the island’s diving tourism industry (Garcia 2018; Stonich 2000). Such inequality appears to be increasing in response to recent growth in the tourism industry, with the majority of wealth from tourism flowing to a small portion of native English-speaking islanders and other Westerners (Davis 2014).

3.2 Focus group interviews

To inform development of our survey questionnaire on child signaling, focus groups of parents of families living in Utila were held in July 2022. Parents indicated frequent sibling competition and various ways children might signal need. Both Spanish-speaking and English-speaking moms reported that fighting between siblings was extremely common, with fights over toys, gifts, and phone time being the most reported causes. In both populations, crying and various forms of sadness and withdrawal were listed as the most common responses to a child not receiving investment or support, followed by temper tantrums. In response to these hypothesized signals, discipline was common. Although the mothers generally reported that children were treated equally, needier children were described as getting more resources from parents, perhaps due to differences in signaling among children as well as information caretakers gained from cues of need.

3.3 Sampling

Participant caregivers for this study were recruited through convenience sampling. JH recruited early participants with the help of primary informants and the use of snowball sampling. Participants were also recruited via Facebook posts.

In all forms of recruitment, participants were informed of the purpose of the study, what they would be asked to do, and the inclusion criteria, such as being 18 or older, having permanent residence on Utila, and having a child between 6 and 18 years old.

3.4 Participants

One hundred forty primary caretakers provided data on 263 children. All participants for the survey portion of the study met the inclusion criteria. Most participants were the biological mothers of one or more children in the study. Several participants were caring for children younger than 6 or older than 18. We collected caregiver reports of signaling for all children 5-20 years old.

3.5 Ethics

All participants provided informed consent. The surveys, which included many topics outside of child signaling, were designed to last about an hour, plus 20 minutes for each additional child. Participants were paid 350 lempiras ($13.84 at the time of writing) for the survey portion of the study.

This study was approved by the WSU and BU IRBs.

3.6 Survey

The data for this study were collected as part of the Utila Child Health Project. Participants could choose to do the survey in English or Spanish. All questions were read to them and recorded by a research team member.

3.6.1 Child signaling frequency and cost, alloparenting contributions, and conflicts with caregiver

We used six-point Likert-type scales to get caregiver reports on the frequencies of 1) various types of child signaling, such as sadness and crying, 2) conflict between the caretaker and each participating child, 3) and child allocare of other children in their household. See Table 1 for exact wording. We gave children an alloparenting frequency of “never” if they were the only child within a household. We also calculated the summed frequency of child alloparenting contributions by other children within the household.

Variable Survey question wording
Crying Frequency How often does your child cry?
Sad Frequency How often is your child sad?
Tantrum Frequency How often does your child throw temper tantrums? (e.g., scream, throws things, or throws themselves on the floor)
Caregiver/Child Conflict Frequency How often do you have conflicts with your child?
Child Alloparenting Frequency How often does your child take care of their other siblings?
Table 1: Variable names and question wording for measures about the frequency of signaling, allocare, and conflict. All questions had the following labels attached to each point on its Likert scale: Never; Once a month or less; More than once a month but less than once a week; More than once a week but not daily; Daily; Multiple times per day. For analyses, we converted these categorical variables to numeric frequencies per month as follows: never = 0; once a month or less = 1; more than once a month = 3; more than once a week = 8; daily = 30; multiple times per day = 60

From these count variables we created two composite signaling variables. The frequency of signaling was the sum of the frequencies of child sadness, crying, and temper tantrums. Signal cost was the sum of the frequencies of these three signals weighted by their relative costliness (i.e., Signal cost = frequency of sadness + 2 \(\times\) frequency of crying + 3 \(\times\) frequency of temper tantrums). Although we treated signal cost as a continuous variable, we conceptualized low signal cost values (e.g., infrequent sadness or crying) as more likely to be minimal signals, and high signal cost values (e.g., frequent crying or temper tantrums) as more likely to be “costly” signals. For each child we also summed the frequencies of conflict with caretakers and signaling cost for all other children in the household, termed Other children conflict and Other children signal cost, respectively.

3.6.2 Relative neediness of children and relative investment in children within the family

We used six-point Likert scales for caretaker reports of 1) the relative neediness of children within the household, and 2) the relative investment they provide to each participating child compared to the rest of their children. Both questions were framed need as involving time, effort, and resources. See Table S1 for exact wording.

3.6.3 Caretaker perceptions of child health and ability to avoid illness

Caretakers were asked about the frequency of their child missing school and their child’s history of medical problems in general terms (i.e., the extent to which they experienced a “variety of medical issues”). Both questions were slightly modified from Hill, Boehm, and Prokosch (2016) and involved the use of five-point Likert scales, the scores of which were averaged for use in analyses. See Table S2 for the wording of these variables.

Caretakers were also asked three questions using a five-point Likert scale about their child’s susceptibility to illness, all of which were slightly modified versions of questions from the Perceived Vulnerability to Disease Scale (Duncan, Schaller, and Park 2009). We reversed the scores on two measures so that a score of 5 corresponded with the lowest susceptibility to illness before we averaged the scores of these to create a mean illness avoidance variable. In the 1 instance in which we only had data for two of the measures, we still calculated the mean but used a numerator of 2. See Table S3 for the wording of these variables.

3.6.4 Caretaker perceptions of home sanitation, neighborhood quality, home instability, and food security

Affirmative caregiver responses to the following questions about their home were summed to create a home sanitation index: having an indoor bathroom, having a bathroom that is not shared with anyone outside of the household, having a flush toilet, having running water to wash hands in the bathroom, and having a home which did not flood in the last year.

Caregiver perceptions of neighborhood quality were measured using ten questions modified from the Neighborhood Characteristics Questionnaire (McGuire 1997). These questions covered the safety and suitability of their neighborhood for raising children and included questions explicitly asking about neighborhood quality, e.g., “Sometimes I hear about illegal drug activity in my neighborhood.” The mean of these values was used in analyses as a neighborhood quality index. Levels of home instability were measured with four questions covering the degree to which the caregiver’s family had/has to move homes and whether people move in and out of their homes frequently. For wording of these items, which used five-point Likert scales, see Table S6 and Table S5.

We used a modified version of the USDA Food Security Questionnaire (Blumberg et al. 1999) to measure food insecurity, with the most significant changes being converting the measures to a five-point Likert scale and averaging them for a food insecurity index. See Table S4 for the wording of these variables.

3.6.5 Causes of, and responses to, the last instance of child signaling of need

We asked caretakers about the last time each participating child was sad or cried. Caretakers provided a free response of the reason(s) for the emotional display, and their responses to it. The researcher then binned responses into at least one of 31 categories which included positive, negative, and neutral responses (from the child’s perspective). For the full list of options see Table S7. We then created a caregiver response variable, which was coded as 1 for a positive response (e.g., helping child), 0 for a neutral response (e.g., not responding), and -1 for a negative response (e.g., punishment; all from the child’s perspective). MG and KS also coded the causes for the presence or absence of 17 elements (e.g., whether the cause involved punishment, family conflict, and/or discomfort, pain, injury, or illness).

3.6.6 Demographic questions

The survey also included many demographic questions about the caretakers and their households. Those used in this study included the (1) ages of those in the household, (2) sexes of those in the household, (3) kinship ties within households, (4) partnership status of the primary caregiver, (5) number of adults who provide childcare within the household, (6) highest level of education of the primary caregiver, (7) immigration status (in regards to Utila), (8) monthly household income, (9) neighborhood of residence, (10) current job of the primary caretaker, and (11) ownership of various possessions (e.g., homes, washing machines, or cellphones; see Table S8 for full list). These data allowed us to calculate the number of children (total, younger, and older) and adults within the household as well as the genetic relatedness between siblings.2 We also created a variable for residence in Camponado, a low-SES, densely populated neighborhood on the island with less sanitation access mostly comprising individuals from the mainland (Garcia, Gurven, and Blackwell 2017).

In one instance where data for caregiver age was missing, we set the missing value to the mean. This affected data for two children.

3.7 Statistical analyses

All statistical analyses were exploratory. Whereas confirmatory studies test prespecified hypotheses generated blind to the data, exploratory analyses are data-driven and prioritize discovery: they risk overfitting the data, generating false positives, but can reveal unexpected yet potentially important relationships that warrant future investigation (Tukey 1977).

The overall structure of our data was analyzed with principal components analysis (PCA), Bayesian graphical models (BGM), and minimum spanning trees (MST). PCA is a linear transformation of the data to a new orthonormal coordinate system in which the first principal component (PC1) corresponds to the axis of maximum variance, the second principal component (PC2) corresponds to the axis perpendicular to the first of the maximum of the remaining variance, and so forth. Among other uses, PCA identifies the linear combinations of variables that account for most of the variance, thereby providing a lower dimensional representation of high dimensional data. In BGM, variables are nodes in an undirected graph, and edges represent their conditional dependencies. Specifically, an edge indicates that two variables are dependent, conditional on the other variables; edge weights indicate the strength and sign of the relationship. Importantly, the absence of an edge indicates that two variables are conditionally independent (Huth et al. 2023). The graph can therefore identify clusters of dependent variables that are independent of other variables. From the graphical models identified with BGM, we extracted an MST, i.e., a subset of the graph in which each node (variable) is connected without any cycles and with the minimum total “distance” between the nodes (more strongly dependent variables, i.e., those with larger absolute weights, having lower “distances”). The MST is therefore typically a dramatically simplified representation of the original graph that often identifies the most important edges among the nodes, which in our case are the most important dependencies among the variables.

To investigate the associations between potential causes of child signaling and conflict with caretakers and caregiver reports of child behavior, we used elasticnet regression models. Elasticnet models are useful in cases where the number of predictor variables (p) is large relative to the number of observations (n). These models, often referred to as penalized or regularized regression (e.g., lasso and ridge regression), aim to limit overfitting the data (variance) by allowing some bias, i.e., by optimizing a bias-variance tradeoff. In particular, lasso regression sets the coefficients of uninformative variables to exactly 0, thereby serving as a form of variable selection (Zou and Hastie 2005).

Elasticnet regression models of signaling and conflict frequency, which were overdispersed count data, were fit using the glmnet package (Friedman, Hastie, and Tibshirani 2010; Wurm, Rathouz, and Hanlon 2021) and the quasipoisson error family. Predictors included demographic, household, health, and neighborhood variables that might cause signaling behavior or conflict between children and caretakers. All variables were centered and standardized by one standard deviation prior to fitting.

Parental responses to child signaling, their perceptions of child need, and their reported investment in the child were coded as three-level ordinal variables, either negative, neutral or positive; or less than other children, same as other children, or more than other children. We analyzed these outcomes using ordinal logistic regression with elastic net penalties, fit with the ordinalNet package (Wurm, Rathouz, and Hanlon 2021).

All analyses were conducted with R version 4.4.1 (2024-06-14).

3.8 Data availability

Study code is available at https://github.com/michaelrgaffney/utilasignaling.

4 Results

One hundred forty primary caretakers (females = 125, males = 8, missing sex = 5) took the survey and provided signaling data for at least one child. Two hundred sixty-three children had frequency data for at least one signal, with 259 having data for all three. Among those with at least one record of signaling frequency, 133 were female and 130 were male. For summary statistics of study variables see Table 2 and Table 4.

N Range Mean SD Histogram
Child age (years) 263.0 5-20 10.5 3.4
Caregiver age (years) 263.0 20-68 35.0 7.9
Sad frequency (times per month) 260.0 0-60 5.0 11.3
Crying frequency (times per month) 262.0 0-60 7.3 12.8
Temper tantrum frequency (times per month) 262.0 0-60 8.5 14.6
Frequency of child's own alloparenting effort (times per month) 244.0 0-60 12.5 18.6
Frequency of other child alloparenting (times per month) 244.0 0-360 25.3 62.1
Frequency of conflict with focal caretaker (times per month) 261.0 0-60 6.7 12.1
Frequency of signals summed (times per month) 263.0 0-180 20.7 31.1
Signal cost 263.0 0-360 45.0 66.7
Frequency of most common signal (times per month) 263.0 0-60 12.2 16.4
Children in household 263.0 1-9 3.1 1.7
Child relatedness 263.0 0.2-1 0.6 0.2
Number of adults in household 263.0 1-5 2.0 0.9
Household adults who provide childcare 261.0 0-5 1.8 0.9
Household adults who provide, food, housework, and other neccesities 261.0 0-5 1.7 0.8
Caregiver education level (years) 247.0 0-17 7.9 3.9
Monthly household income (Lempira) 259.0 2500-120000 11061.8 11257.3
Household food insecurity 261.0 6-30 21.5 8.7
Neighborhood quality index 261.0 1-5 3.6 1.1
Other children conflict 261.0 0-90 7.8 14.2
Other children signal cost 263.0 0-737 67.8 107.8
House sanitation index 260.0 0-5 3.7 1.4
Table 2: Summary statistics for continuous variables.
N Range Mean SD Histogram
Caregiver age (years) 135.0 20-68 34.9 8.5
Children in household 135.0 1-9 2.4 1.4
Number of adults in household 135.0 1-5 2.0 0.9
Household adults who provide childcare 135.0 0-5 1.8 0.9
Household adults who provide, food, housework, and other neccesities 135.0 0-5 1.7 0.8
Caregiver education level (years) 129.0 0-17 8.3 3.8
Monthly household income (Lempira) 133.0 2500-120000 11710.5 13017.2
Household food insecurity 135.0 6-30 20.5 8.7
Neighborhood quality index 135.0 1-5 3.7 1.1
House sanitation index 134.0 0-5 3.9 1.3
Possession score 135.0 0-8 3.9 2.0
Table 3: Summary statistics for continuous variables.
N %
Child sex Female 75 55.6
Male 60 44.4
Primary language EN 14 10.4
ES-ES 121 89.6
Immigrant No 29 21.5
Yes 106 78.5
Partnered status Partnered 94 69.6
Unpartnered 41 30.4
Relative need (w/in household) Much less 0 0.0
Less 8 5.9
The same amount 38 28.1
More 36 26.7
Much more 6 4.4
Relative caretaker investment (w/in household) Much less 0 0.0
Less 16 11.9
The same amount 62 45.9
More 10 7.4
Much more 2 1.5
Residence in Camponado No 74 54.8
Yes 61 45.2
Stay at home mother No 97 71.9
Yes 38 28.1
Possession: Motor vehicle 0 59 43.7
1 76 56.3
Possession: Bicycle 0 99 73.3
1 36 26.7
Possession: TV with cable 0 63 46.7
1 72 53.3
Possession: Smartphone 0 25 18.5
1 110 81.5
Possession: Washing machine 0 57 42.2
1 78 57.8
Possession: Refrigerator 0 47 34.8
1 88 65.2
Possession: Home 0 98 72.6
1 37 27.4
Possession: Credit card 0 99 73.3
1 36 26.7
Caregiver Sex Female 123 91.1
Male 8 5.9
Table 4: Summary statistics for factor variables.

A PCA of primary study variables found that the child signaling variables and the sociodemographic and ecological variables loaded primarily on PC1, in a direction suggesting that greater signaling covaried with more adverse environments. Household composition variables loaded primarily on PC2, covarying with child signaling variables in a direction suggesting that larger households covaried with less signaling. See Figure 1.

  1. Loadings of each variable on PC1 and PC2. b) Biplot of PC1 and PC2. Each point is one child. Arrows represent the loadings of each variable on PC1 and PC2. Variables with small loading factors not displayed
Figure 1

We then estimated a BGM for all study variables, extracting the MST, which revealed that signaling variables clustered together, conflict was positively associated with signal cost, and child age negatively associated with crying frequency. See Figure 2.

Figure 2: Minimum spanning tree derived from a Bayesian graphical model of child signaling and variables thought to cause differences in signaling strategies. Purple edges represent negative partial correlations between variables. Orange edges represent positive partial correlations between variables. Line weights represent partial correlation coefficients. Red dots indicate the two variables (child age and conflict) that are closest to the signaling variables. Blue text represents our interpretation of the main clusters

4.1 Distributions of signaling behavior, alloparenting effort, and conflict

Child sadness, crying, and temper tantrums were common and highly correlated with one another. See Figure 3 and Figure 4. Caregivers reported that 64 children (25%) were sad at least once a week, 102 children (39%) cried at least once a week, and 100 children (38%) threw temper tantrums at least once a week. A small subset of children engaged in these signals/states at least daily; sadness: 16 children (6.2%); crying: 31 children (12%); and tantrums: 42 children (16%). However, many children were reported to never engage in these signals/states; sadness: 78 children (30%); crying; 58 children (22%); and tantrums: 90 children (34%). For a visualization of how signal frequencies varied within children, see Figure S1.

Conflict between children and caretakers was also common, with 92 children (35%) having conflicts with parents more than once a week. However, 109 children (42%) were described as never having conflicts with parents. See Figure S2. Conflict was also associated with higher signaling frequencies. See Figure 1 and Figure 4.

The frequency of child alloparenting effort, which previous research has linked to parent-child conflict, was bimodally distributed, with 137 children (56%) reported to never engage in it (36 instances were due to a child being an only child) and 78 children (32%) reported to help with childcare at least once a day. See Figure S2.

Figure 3: Frequencies of child sadness, crying, and temper tantrums per month as reported by the primary caretaker. Frequency key: 0 corresponds to “never,” <=1 corresponds to “once a month or less,” 2-3 corresponds to “more than once a month but less than once a week,” 4-29 corresponds to “more than once a week but not daily,” 30 corresponds to “daily,” and >30 corresponds to “multiple times per day”

Figure 4: Correlation matrix of the frequencies of signals/states covered in the study with sex, child age, and the frequency of conflict between children and primary caretakers. For a more complete correlation matrix of study variables see Figure S3

4.2 Predictors of signaling frequency and conflict frequency

Using lasso regression, we explored all potential predictors of each child signal frequency, as well as of conflict frequency. Child age was a strong negative predictor of all frequencies, and Neighborhood quality was too, albeit less so for Crying and not for Sadness. Medical problems was a weak positive predictor for all frequencies. Possession of a bicycle or washing machine was a positive predictor of Signaling Frequency” and Signal Cost, whereas some other possessions were negative predictors of various frequencies. Possession of a TV with cable was the strongest negative predictor of Sadness, for example. Male sex was associated with higher Conflict frequency* with the primary caretaker. See Figure 5.

Figure 5: Lasso regression models of each child signaling frequency and conflict frequency. Variables whose coefficient values were shrunk to 0 are not displayed. Models fit using quasi-Poisson regression

The effects of particularly large and consistent risk or protective factors for child signaling identified by the lasso regressions (Figure 5) are shown in Figure 6 and Figure S4.

Figure 6: Effects of selected predictors of child signaling frequencies when holding continuous variables at their mean and factor variables at their mode

Although child age was negatively associated with all signaling frequencies, a general linear mixed effects negative binomial model showed that the negative association was strongest for Crying and for males (Figure S5).

The effects of particularly large risk or protective factors for conflict frequency are shown in Figure 7.

Figure 7: Effects of selected predictors of child-parent conflict frequencies when holding continuous variables at their mean and factor variables at their mode

In general, older child age and better neighborhoods were associated with less conflict and less signaling, whereas medical problems were associated with more conflict and more signaling. There was little evidence for a sex difference in signaling, except that alloparenting frequency was positively associated with signaling for girls, and negatively for boys. Male sex was associated with more conflict.

4.3 Positive associations between child age and signaling frequency and perceptions of child neediness

Primary caretakers rarely described a child as “much less” 1 children (0.5%) [fix in word doc?] or “much more” 10 children (5%) needy compared to their other children. Therefore, we collapsed “less” and “much less” into a “less” factor and “more” and “much more” into a “more” factor. The result was 27 less needy children, 106 children who were as needy as their siblings, and 68 more needy children.

There were positive relationships between perceived relative neediness within the family and both child age and the frequency of child sadness. See Figure 8.

Figure 8: The proportion of children perceived by caretakers as being more needy, as needy, or less needy than a caretaker’s other children when holding continuous variables at their mean and factor variables at their mode. a: Effect of child age on the probability of relative neediness. b: Effect of child sadness frequency on the probability of relative neediness. Outcome variable question wording: How much time, effort, and resources does this child need compared to your other children?

4.4 Relative need predicts relative investment

Signals can elicit better treatment because the information they provide alters the behavior of signal targets in ways that benefit the signaler. For this reason, we tested the association between caretaker perceptions of relative child need within the household and the caretaker’s relative investment within the household. Consistent with signaling theory, our model predicts a greater proportion of caretakers investing more in children who they deem needier and a greater proportion of caretakers investing less in children they deem less needy, controlling for the age of the child, and household demographics. See Figure 9.

Figure 9: The effect of perceived need (in terms of time, effort, and resources) on the probability of relative investment within the household when holding continuous variables at their mean and factor variables at their mode. Outcome variable question wording: How much time, effort, and resources do you put into this child compared to your other children?

4.5 Caregiver responses to most recent signal of need

Figure 10: Frequencies of caregiver response to the last instance of child signaling by the cause of the signaling. Categories of causes were based on cluster analysis of more fine-grained cause variables. See Figure S6 for cluster dendrogram and Table S9 for the frequencies of causes and caregiver responses

There were 6 instances in which a caregiver’s response involved acts which were both negative and positive from the child’s perspective. These were excluded from analyses due to their rarity.

Our models found no evidence of relationships between, child age, child sex, the number of children in the household, and log family income and the valence of parental responses (positive, neutral, or negative) from the child’s perspective. However, primary caretakers were more likely to respond positively towards a child when they attributed the cause of signaling to discomfort, pain, injury, or illness, and less likely to respond positively when they attributed the cause of signaling to family conflict, child punishment, child transgressions, or a child losing an item or privileges. See Figure 11.

Figure 11: Effects of selected predictors of the probability of positive, neutral, and negative responses to the last time a child became sad or cried when holding continuous variables at their mean and factor variables at their mode. 1 = evidence of the cause in the caregiver report; 0 = no evidence. The endpoints of the lines are dodged slightly for greater visibility. Dot size represents model predictions for each participant given their values of predictor variables. See Figure S7 for the effect of the cause involving punishment

5 Discussion

Caregivers reported a wide range of child signaling frequencies. About half of children were reported to cry or throw tantrums more than once a month, and almost 40% were reported to do so more than once a week (Figure 3), with higher frequencies in younger children, lower frequencies in older children, and particularly steep age-related declines for crying and for all types of signaling by males (Figure S5).

Our bivariate correlations, PCA, MST, and lasso regression analyses all provided a consistent pattern of results: child age was a strong negative predictor of signaling frequency and cost; conflict with the primary caretaker was a positive predictor of signaling frequency and cost; and multiple indices of adversity, such as low neighborhood quality, low household income, and medical problems, were positive predictors of signaling frequency and cost (Figure 1, Figure 2, Figure 4, Figure 5, Figure 6).

Contrary to expectations, immigration status, residence in Camponado, and primary language (Spanish or English as proxies for cultural differences), did not predict child signaling in our lasso regressions, despite the differences in wealth, job certainty, discrimination, and living conditions between those from the mainland and English speaking Utilians (Davis 2014; Garcia, Gurven, and Blackwell 2017; Garcia 2018; Stonich 2000). These variables correlated with neighborhood quality, however, which was retained in our models, and lasso regression tends to retain only one of a set of correlated predictors (Zou and Hastie 2005). Additionally, families from Camponado appeared to be willing to care for children outside their immediate families, which might have reduced children’s needs.

Consistent with signaling models that emphasize the role of conflicts of interest in favoring the use of signals with honesty-enforcing mechanisms (e.g., “costly” signals), caregiver perceptions of conflict and child signaling frequency were positively correlated (Figure 4), and family conflict was the most common cause of a child’s recent signaling episode (Figure 10). Conflicts, in turn, were negatively associated with child age and higher neighborhood quality, and positively associated with male sex, medical problems, and (oddly) caregiver education (Figure 7). Although conflicts of interest do not always lead to overt behavioral conflict (Altmann 1980; Bateson 1994), it is likely many, if not most, conflicts are ultimately caused by conflicts of interest.

Consistent with the need signaling hypothesis, more frequent sadness was positively associated with perceptions of relative child need within the household (Figure 8). Higher perceived need, in turn, was associated with higher relative investment (Figure 9). Crying and tantrums were not associated with higher perceived need, likely due to their high correlation with sadness and the propensity of lasso regression to retain only one of a set of correlated predictors (Zou and Hastie 2005). Signaling behavior did not predict differences in relative caregiver investment beyond its effect on perceived need Figure S9, similar to an experimental vignette study that found that the likelihood of costly support was largely mediated by the effect of costly signaling on belief in need (Gaffney et al. 2022).

Interestingly, older children were perceived to be needier than younger ones (Figure 8). One likely reason for this might be that caretakers perceive the types of investment older children seek as more costly. In line with this reasoning, multiple caretakers mentioned that older kids need more money and advice and get into trouble more often. It might also be that caretakers see investing in older children as relatively costly when they seek to redirect investment to younger children, whose needs might be perceived to be more legitimate.

Keeping in mind possible biases, caregiver self-reported responses to signals of need were generally positive or neutral, more so for situations involving injury and illness, and less so for situations involving family conflict, loss of privileges, and transgressions, which had greater proportions of negative responses (Figure 10; Figure 11). These patterns probably reflect a combination of shared interests vs. conflicts of interest between child and caretaker, some of which might represent caretaker investment in some children more than others, and greater caretaker certainty about need in cases of injury and illness. Negative responses, e.g., punishment, can be used to change future child behavior that is costly to the caregiver (e.g., harming siblings or wasting resources), and possibly also to signal the costliness of providing the desired support (Hagen and Syme 2024; Gaffney et al. 2022). That said, our model predicts positive responses in 35% of cases involving transgressions, suggesting that children are successful in negotiating better outcomes at least some of the time.

Our results parallel those of previous studies of infants and young children that found that, outside of peaks in infancy and early childhood, the frequencies of crying and temper tantrums decrease with age (Macfarlane, Allen, and Honzik 1954; Ward 1970; Österman and Björkqvist 2010; Vermillet et al. 2022; Barr et al. 1991; Potegal and Davidson 2003; Bhatia et al. 1990). Studies examining crying and tantrums in later childhood and adolescence are rare, especially for crying (Rottenberg and Vingerhoets 2012; Zeifman 2013). Our findings suggest the frequency of crying continues to decrease into childhood, dropping precipitously as children grow older. The frequency of temper tantrums also declined, as did the frequency of child sadness, albeit at a much slower rate (Figure 5, Figure 6). Our results also align with studies examining responses to the crying and fussing of infants that have shown that they often lead to increased support (e.g., breastfeeding, attention, or maintaining proximity, Lin and McFatter 2012; Kushnick 2006; Kruger and Konner 2010; Hewlett et al. 1998; Chaudhary, Salali, and Swanepoel 2024; Tronick, Morelli, and Winn 1987), but can also lead to negative responses like abuse (Zeevenhooven et al. 2018; Kurth et al. 2011; Howard et al. 2006; Soltis 2004).

Our results are consistent with the hypothesis that sadness, crying, and tantrums are signals of need, that children’s need is higher in adverse environments and at younger ages, that costly signals rather than minimal ones are often needed to ensure credibility when there are conflicts of interest between caregivers and children, and that signals of need are effective at increasing caregiver perceptions of need that ultimately lead to increased investment in children.

Many models designed to explain signals of need (e.g., the begging of young birds) predict that offspring who are worse off or are receiving less investment have more to gain from signaling than those with more (Mock, Dugas, and Strickler 2011; Godfray 1991; Caro et al. 2016; Godfray and Johnstone 2000) and multiple game theoretical models examining parent-offspring conflict have found that parental resources have a modest impact on the evolutionary stable value for offspring demand for resources (Bossan, Hammerstein, and Koehncke 2013; Mock and Parker 1997). In line with this reasoning, children in lower income households and riskier environments might benefit more from signaling effort if they experience greater levels of adversity or perceive themselves as disadvantaged compared to other children.

One possible reason for the negative association of signaling with age, which is also seen in more industrialized settings (Zeifman 2013; Potegal and Davidson 2003; Koch 2003; Macfarlane, Allen, and Honzik 1954), is that as children mature, they are more capable of fulfilling their own needs, more able to verbalize what they need (Österman and Björkqvist 2010), and less vulnerable to threats. The effects of age on signaling are also likely due to how age influences the costliness of signaling need. For example, although the energetic cost of crying might be costly for the youngest children, it is likely insignificant for older children. Older children might instead need to weigh the potential social costs of crying or otherwise expressing sadness (Glasberg and Aboud 1981, 1982; Zeman and Garber 1996) against the potential increase in social support, which is consistent with our result that the age-related decline in signaling was steepest for crying. The age-related decline in signaling was also generally steeper for males than females (Figure S5).

Previous research has shown family demands, such as caring for younger siblings (alloparenting), is an important source of parent-offspring conflict (Syme and Hagen 2023). Although there was little evidence for sex differences in signaling overall (perhaps because sex differences typically emerge in adolescence, and our sample of adolescents was small), there was evidence that sex interacted with alloparenting effort. We found that higher frequencies of alloparenting by girls was associated with a higher frequency of tantrums and overall signaling costs, whereas for boys this relationship was slightly negative (Figure S4). In many societies, girls do more alloparenting than boys (Helfrecht and Meehan 2016; Weisner and Gallimore 1977; Barry and Paxson 1971; Turke 1988), which matches reports from our focus groups of mothers. It is plausible that older girls are pressured to do more care of their younger siblings, in line with other studies finding an association between household responsibilities, like caregiving, and parent-offspring conflict (Lowe 2003; Syme and Hagen 2023). If so, girls with excessive alloparenting responsibilities might be signaling their need for more time to invest in peer relationships and status seeking behaviors outside the household. Although our study found a small negative association between girls’ alloparenting and caregiver reports of conflict (Figure 5), when girls do what caregivers want, caregivers plausibly report less conflict.

5.1 Limitations

Although this study was broader than most in that it examined sadness, crying, and temper tantrums across much of childhood and adolescence, it did not cover all the ways that caregivers might infer need, such as cues of injury. It also did not investigate all potential signals of need. For example, Spanish-speaking mothers reported in focus groups that refusing to do homework was a common tactic. Pained facial and bodily expressions (Vigil and Strenth 2014; Craig 2009; Cano and Williams 2010; Schiavenato and Craig 2010), self-harm outside of temper tantrums (Hagen, Watson, and Hammerstein 2008; Nock 2008), and suicidality (Syme, Garfield, and Hagen 2016) have all been suggested to credibly signal need in times of conflicts of interest and may be viable strategies for children, at least at certain ages. Running away has received similar treatment, especially in instances when it comes with substantial risk (Shostak 1981) or is seen as a suicide-threat (Fischer 1950; Syme and Hagen 2023). English-speaking mothers in our focus groups emphasized self-harm (e.g., a child slamming their head on the ground) and running away. However, in Utila running away often involves children visiting neighbors or aunts and is much less risky than it would be in many parts of mainland Honduras (Dávila-Cervantes and Pardo-Montaño 2024). Despite the relative safety of Utila, young children may still face risks out on their own due to proximity to the ocean and the presence of dogs, motorcycles, golf carts, and tuk-tuks (auto rickshaws) on the narrow roads typical of much of the populated parts of the island. Due to uncertainty on how to conceptualize the risks involved, we did not include running away in our analyses.

The main limitation of this study is self-report bias: all data come from caregiver reports, and therefore, reflect the biases of caretakers, whatever those might be. For example, caregivers might have reported more investment in children or fairer distribtions of resources than was actually the case. In addition, questions about neighborhood quality lacked a reference, so some caregivers might have compared their neighborhoods to mainland neighborhoods and others to island neighborhoods.

Another important limitation is that this study was exploratory: such data-driven analyses can reveal unexpected relationships and inspire new theory but also risk overfitting the data, suggesting associations that might not exist. Our study was also cross-sectional, further limiting our ability to make causal inferences. In particular, there is likely a bidirectional relationship between child signaling and caregivers’ perceptions of conflict that our study design could not disentangle. Furthermore, our penalized regressions included many variables, some of which might have been colliders, inducing spurious associations between outcome and predictor variables. We also assumed a priori that, at least in young children, infrequent sadness and crying were minimal signals not requiring a costly honesty-enforcing mechanism, whereas frequent sadness and crying, as well as tantrums, were costly signals.

Our use of convenience and snowball sampling is also a limitation as it resulted in a non-probability sample which may not be representative of the broader population. This could happen if there was selection bias so that those who participated differed from the rest of the population in how they interacted with their children or how they assessed, remembered, and reported child behavior.

6 Conclusion

Children face the challenge of eliciting support from others in times of adversity and opportunity. On the island of Utila, child signaling strategies were highly correlated with each other, and were exhibited by children of all ages, albeit more frequently by younger children and those living in more adverse conditions, who plausibly had greater need. Consistent with signaling models that emphasize the role of conflicts of interest in favoring the use of costlier signals, child signaling effort was positively correlated with the frequency of conflict with caretakers and with perceptions of need, and greater perceptions of child need predicted greater investment in a given child. Our results suggest that evolutionary theories of signaling can help explain patterns of child sadness, crying, and temper tantrums.

7 Supplementary Information

7.1 Additional information for survey measures

Variable Survey question wording
Relative Need How much time, effort, and resources does this child need compared to your other children?
Relative Investment How much time, effort, and resources do you put into this child compared to your other children?
Table S1: Variable names and question wording for measures about relative need and investment. Both questions had the following labels attached to each point on its Likert scale: Much less; Less; The same amount; More; Much more.
Variable Survey question wording
SchoolAges1 My child has missed a lot of school due to illness.
SchoolAges2 My child has had to deal with a variety of medical issues in their life so far.
Table S2: Variable names and question wording for measures about a child’s health history. Both questions were asked using a Likert scale from 1-5 where 1 was labeled “Strongly disagree” and 5 was labeled “Strongly agree.”
Variable Survey question wording
IllnessAvoidance1 If an illness is ‘going around’, my child will get it.
IllnessAvoidance2 In general, my child is very susceptible to colds, flu, and other infectious diseases
IllnessAvoidance3 My child’s immune system protects him/her from most illnesses that other kids get.
Table S3: Variable names and question wording for measures about a child’s current likelihood of resisting illness. All three questions were asked using a Likert scale from 1-5 where 1 was labeled “Strongly disagree” and 5 was labeled “Strongly agree.” The scores for IllnessAvoidance1 and IllnessAvoidance2 were inverted so that 5 corresponded with the lowest susceptibility to illness, i.e., greatest illness avoidance.
Variable Survey question wording
FoodSecurity_1 In the past year, the food that we bought often didn’t last, and we didn’t have money to get more.
FoodSecurity_2 In the past year, we couldn’t afford to eat balanced meals.
FoodSecurity_3 In the past year, I (or other adults in my household) sometimes cut the size of my meals or skipped meals because there wasn’t enough money for food.
FoodSecurity_4 In the past year, I sometimes ate less than I felt I should because there wasn’t enough money for food.
FoodSecurity_5 In the past year, I was sometimes hungry but didn’t eat because there wasn’t enough money for food.
FoodSecurity_6 In the past year, I ate lower quality food because I couldn’t afford better food.
Table S4: Variable names and question wording for the modified version of the USDA Food Security Questionnaire (Blumberg et al. 1999). All questions were asked using a Likert scale from 1-5 where 1 was labeled “Strongly disagree” and 5 was labeled “Strongly agree.”
Variable Survey question wording
HomeInstability_1 We move our home a lot.
HomeInstability_2 I wish our household felt more stable.
HomeInstability_3 I worry that we will be forced to move before we are ready.
HomeInstability_4 People move in and move out of our home frequently.
Table S5: Variable names and question wording for the home instability questions. All questions were asked using a Likert scale from 1-5 where 1 was labeled “Disagree strongly” and 5 was labeled “Agree Strongly.”
Variable Survey question wording
NeighborhoodQuality_1 As a place to live, my neighborhood is good quality.
NeighborhoodQuality_2 As a place to raise children, my neighborhood is good quality.
NeighborhoodQuality_3 My neighborhood quality has gotten worse over time.
NeighborhoodQuality_4 My neighborhood is more dangerous than other parts of the island.
NeighborhoodQuality_5 Sometimes I hear about a fight with a weapon in my neighborhood.
NeighborhoodQuality_6 Sometimes I hear about illegal drug activity in my neighborhood.
NeighborhoodQuality_7 Sometimes I hear about someone being badly hurt in my neighborhood.
NeighborhoodQuality_8 Sometimes I hear about someone’s home being robbed in my neighborhood.
NeighborhoodQuality_9 Sometimes I hear about someone being mugged in my neighborhood.
NeighborhoodQuality_10 Sometimes I hear about someone being assaulted in my neighborhood.
Table S6: Variable names and question wording for the perceptions of neighborhood quality questions. All questions were asked using a Likert scale from 1-5 where 1 was labeled “Strongly disagree” and 5 was labeled “Strongly agree.”

Positive: Give resources (e.g., toys, food, money)
Positive: Promise resources
Positive: Give attention/affection
Positive: Promise attention/affection
Positive: Give opportunities (e.g., loosen restrictions, new privileges, time with friends, fun activities)
Positive: Promise opportunities
Positive: Remove responsibilities (e.g., fewer chores)
Positive: Promise removal of responsibilities
Positive: Take child’s side in conflict (e.g., taking child’s side against sibling, intervening against bully)
Positive: Give advice
Positive: Other [Text Box]
Neutral: Distract
Neutral: Do nothing
Neutral: Explain (e.g., go over why the child cannot have or do something)
Neutral: Other [Text Box]
Negative: Threaten removal of resources
Negative: Remove resources (e.g., toys, food, money)
Negative: Threaten withholding of attention/affection
Negative: Withhold attention/affection (e.g., silent treatment, ignoring)
Negative: Threaten loss of opportunities (e.g., freedom to move around the island, beach time, timeout, time with friends)
Negative: Loss of opportunities
Negative: Threaten more responsibilities (e.g., chores, alloparenting, homework)
Negative: Add responsibilities
Negative: Support adversary (e.g., taking sibling’s side)
Negative: Threaten physical punishment
Negative: Punish physically
Negative: Punish verbally (includes yelling)
Negative: Downplay adversity
Negative: Other [Text Box]
NA (Can’t remember, refuse to answer, etc)
Other: Other [Text Box]

Table S7: List of options for research assistants to classify participant responses to the question of how they responded when their child was last sad or cried.

Motorized vehicle (scooter, 4-wheeler, etc.)
Bicycle
Television (TV) with cable
Smartphone
Washing machine
Refrigerator
A home that you own
Credit card

Table S8: List of possessions owned (yes or no).

7.2 Figures

Figure S1: Combinations of signaling frequencies per month. Alluvium width equals the number of individuals with the same frequencies for the three signals/states. Stratum height equals the count of individuals at a given frequency. Frequency key: Low includes “never” and “once a month or less,” medium includes “more than once a month but less than once a week” and “more than once a week but not daily,” high includes “daily,” and “multiple times per day.”

Figure S2: Left: Frequency of conflict (per month) between child and primary caregiver as reported by primary caretaker. Right: Frequency of a child’s alloparenting effort (per month) as reported by primary caretaker. Color corresponds to sex of the child. Frequency key: 0 corresponds to “never,” <=1 corresponds to “once a month or less,” 2-3 corresponds to “more than once a month but less than once a week,” 4-29 corresponds to “more than once a week but not daily,” 30 corresponds to “daily,” and >30 corresponds to “multiple times per day.”
Figure S3: Complete correlation matrix of study variables.
Figure S4: Effects of alloparenting frequency (per month) and signal cost and frequency of temper tantrums by sex when holding continuous variables at their mean and factor variables at their mode.

Figure S5: Effects plots of a negative binomial model of signal frequency as a function of signal type by child age and neighborhood quality.

Figure S6: Hierarchical cluster analysis dendrogram for the causes of child signaling. Method: Euclidean distances between variables agglomerated with the ward.D2 algorithm.
Figure S7: The likelihood of positive, neutral, and negative responses to the last time a child became sad or cried when punishment was implicated in the cause when holding continuous variables at their mean and factor variables at their mode. 1 = evidence of the cause involving punishment. 0 = no evidence of the cause involving punishment. The endpoints of the lines are dodged slightly for greater visibility. Dot size represents model predictions for each participant given their values of predictor variables.

7.3 Tables

N %
ConflictFamily No 116 44.1
Yes 147 55.9
ConflictFamilyOverPeers No 241 91.6
Yes 22 8.4
ConflictSibling No 238 90.5
Yes 25 9.5
ConflictOutsideFamily No 249 94.7
Yes 14 5.3
DeathORIllnessInjuryHarmInOthers No 249 94.7
Yes 14 5.3
HouseholdAdversity No 257 97.7
Yes 6 2.3
ExplicitInvestmentDesired No 240 91.3
Yes 23 8.7
ActivityDesired No 225 85.6
Yes 38 14.4
UnwantedTask No 233 88.6
Yes 30 11.4
Punishment No 236 89.7
Yes 27 10.3
PhysicalAggression No 259 98.5
Yes 4 1.5
LossOfPrivlegesOrItem No 243 92.4
Yes 20 7.6
TransgressionMade No 231 87.8
Yes 32 12.2
FearAnxiety No 256 97.3
Yes 7 2.7
DiscomfortPainInjuryIllness No 235 89.4
Yes 28 10.6
SeparationAttentionSeeking No 229 87.1
Yes 34 12.9
StatusConcerns No 257 97.7
Yes 6 2.3
Table S9: Frequencies of various causes of the last time each child was sad or cried as reported by caretakers.

7.4 Coefficient plots

Figure S8: Effects of predictor variables on relative need between household children. Ordinal logistic regression model with elastic net penalties.
Figure S9: Effects of predictor variables on relative investment in household children. Ordinal logistic regression model with elastic net penalties.
Figure S10: Effects of predictor variables on caregiver responses to the last time a child was sad or cried. Ordinal logistic regression model with elastic net penalties.
R version 4.4.1 (2024-06-14)
Platform: aarch64-apple-darwin20
Running under: macOS 15.5

Matrix products: default
BLAS:   /Library/Frameworks/R.framework/Versions/4.4-arm64/Resources/lib/libRblas.0.dylib 
LAPACK: /Library/Frameworks/R.framework/Versions/4.4-arm64/Resources/lib/libRlapack.dylib;  LAPACK version 3.12.0

locale:
[1] en_US.UTF-8/en_US.UTF-8/en_US.UTF-8/C/en_US.UTF-8/en_US.UTF-8

time zone: America/Los_Angeles
tzcode source: internal

attached base packages:
[1] stats     graphics  grDevices datasets  utils     methods   base     

other attached packages:
 [1] effects_4.2-2            carData_3.0-5            glmmTMB_1.1.11          
 [4] ordinalNet_2.12          ggraph_2.2.1             tidygraph_1.3.1         
 [7] easybgm_0.2.1            marginaleffects_0.24.0   poissonreg_1.0.1        
[10] yardstick_1.3.1          workflowsets_1.1.0       workflows_1.1.4         
[13] tune_1.2.1               tidyr_1.3.1              tibble_3.2.1            
[16] rsample_1.2.1            recipes_1.1.0            parsnip_1.2.1           
[19] modeldata_1.4.0          infer_1.0.7              dials_1.3.0             
[22] scales_1.3.0             broom_1.0.7              tidymodels_1.2.0        
[25] glmnet_4.1-8             Matrix_1.7-1             skimr_2.1.5             
[28] ggalluvial_0.12.5        pvclust_2.2-0            ggcorrplot_0.1.4.1      
[31] modelsummary_2.2.0       patchwork_1.3.0          forcats_1.0.0           
[34] ggplot2_3.5.1            utiladata2023_0.0.0.9000 labelled_2.13.0         
[37] stringr_1.5.1            purrr_1.0.2              dplyr_1.1.4             

loaded via a namespace (and not attached):
  [1] matrixStats_1.4.1        lubridate_1.9.3          DiceDesign_1.10         
  [4] RColorBrewer_1.1-3       insight_1.0.0            repr_1.1.7              
  [7] numDeriv_2016.8-1.1      tools_4.4.1              backports_1.5.0         
 [10] utf8_1.2.4               R6_2.5.1                 QRM_0.4-31              
 [13] mgcv_1.9-1               withr_3.0.2              Brobdingnag_1.2-9       
 [16] GGally_2.2.1             gridExtra_2.3            fdrtool_1.2.18          
 [19] qgraph_1.9.8             quantreg_5.99.1          cli_3.6.4               
 [22] HDInterval_0.2.4         network_1.18.2           sandwich_3.1-1          
 [25] labeling_0.4.3           slam_0.1-55              mvtnorm_1.3-2           
 [28] robustbase_0.99-4-1      tables_0.9.31            ggridges_0.5.6          
 [31] pbapply_1.7-2            QuickJSR_1.4.0           systemfonts_1.1.0       
 [34] pbivnorm_0.6.0           StanHeaders_2.32.10      foreign_0.8-87          
 [37] svglite_2.1.3            MCMCpack_1.7-1           scico_1.5.0             
 [40] parallelly_1.40.1        rstudioapi_0.17.1        generics_0.1.3          
 [43] shape_1.4.6.1            gtools_3.9.5             inline_0.3.20           
 [46] loo_2.8.0                fansi_1.0.6              abind_1.4-8             
 [49] lifecycle_1.0.4          yaml_2.3.10              grid_4.4.1              
 [52] lavaan_0.6-19            metaBMA_0.6.9            lattice_0.22-6          
 [55] haven_2.5.4              lpSolveAPI_5.5.2.0-17.12 sna_2.8                 
 [58] pillar_1.9.0             knitr_1.49               bain_0.2.11             
 [61] boot_1.3-31              estimability_1.5.1       corpcor_1.6.10          
 [64] BDgraph_2.73             future.apply_1.11.3      codetools_0.2-20        
 [67] glue_1.8.0               data.table_1.16.2        vctrs_0.6.5             
 [70] png_0.1-8                Rdpack_2.6.2             gtable_0.3.6            
 [73] cachem_1.1.0             gower_1.0.1              xfun_0.49               
 [76] rbibutils_2.3            BGGM_2.1.3               prodlim_2024.06.25      
 [79] survey_4.4-2             pracma_2.4.4             reformulas_0.4.0        
 [82] coda_0.19-4.1            survival_3.7-0           timeDate_4041.110       
 [85] iterators_1.0.14         BFpack_1.4.0             hardhat_1.4.0           
 [88] lava_1.8.0               ipred_0.9-15             mcmc_0.9-8              
 [91] nlme_3.1-166             rstan_2.32.6             LaplacesDemon_16.1.6    
 [94] TMB_1.9.17               rpart_4.1.23             DBI_1.2.3               
 [97] colorspace_2.1-1         Hmisc_5.2-1              nnet_7.3-19             
[100] mnormt_2.1.1             tidyselect_1.2.1         timeSeries_4041.111     
[103] compiler_4.4.1           tinytable_0.6.1          htmlTable_2.4.3         
[106] SparseM_1.84-2           bgms_0.1.4               checkmate_2.3.2         
[109] DEoptimR_1.1-3-1         psych_2.4.6.26           quadprog_1.5-8          
[112] digest_0.6.37            minqa_1.2.8              rmarkdown_2.29          
[115] extraDistr_1.10.0        htmltools_0.5.8.1        pkgconfig_2.0.3         
[118] jpeg_0.1-10              base64enc_0.1-3          lme4_1.1-35.5           
[121] lhs_1.2.0                fastmap_1.2.0            rlang_1.1.5             
[124] htmlwidgets_1.6.4        Bergm_5.0.7              farver_2.1.2            
[127] zoo_1.8-12               jsonlite_1.8.9           statnet.common_4.10.0   
[130] magrittr_2.0.3           Formula_1.2-5            munsell_0.5.1           
[133] GPfit_1.0-8              Rcpp_1.0.13-1            viridis_0.6.5           
[136] furrr_0.3.1              stringi_1.8.4            logspline_2.1.22        
[139] Rglpk_0.6-5.1            MASS_7.3-61              plyr_1.8.9              
[142] pkgbuild_1.4.5           ggstats_0.7.0            matrixcalc_1.0-6        
[145] ggrepel_0.9.6            parallel_4.4.1           listenv_0.9.1           
[148] graphlayouts_1.2.1       splines_4.4.1            hms_1.1.3               
[151] igraph_2.1.1             reshape2_1.4.4           stats4_4.4.1            
[154] rstantools_2.4.0         rle_0.9.2                evaluate_1.0.1          
[157] trust_0.1-8              mitools_2.4              RcppParallel_5.1.9      
[160] renv_1.0.11              tweenr_2.0.3             nloptr_2.1.1            
[163] foreach_1.5.2            MatrixModels_0.5-3       polyclip_1.10-7         
[166] future_1.34.0            reshape_0.8.9            ggforce_0.4.2           
[169] ergm_4.7.5               viridisLite_0.4.2        glasso_1.11             
[172] class_7.3-22             gsl_2.1-8                memoise_2.0.1           
[175] cluster_2.1.6            timechange_0.3.0         globals_0.16.3          
[178] bridgesampling_1.1-2    

8 References

Albino, R. C., and V. J. Thompson. 1956. “The effects of sudden weaning on Zulu children.” The British Journal of Medical Psychology 29 (3-4): 177–210. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.2044-8341.1956.tb00914.x.
Altmann, Jeanne. 1980. Baboon mothers and infants. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press.
Andrews, Paul W., and J. Anderson Thomson. 2009. “The Bright Side of Being Blue: Depression as an Adaptation for Analyzing Complex Problems.” Psychological Review 116 (3): 620–54. https://doi.org/10.1037/a0016242.
Apicella, Coren L., and Joan B. Silk. 2019. “The Evolution of Human Cooperation.” Current Biology 29 (11): R447–50. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cub.2019.03.036.
Balsters, Martijn J. H., Emiel J. Krahmer, Marc G. J. Swerts, and Ad J. J. M. Vingerhoets. 2013. “Emotional Tears Facilitate the Recognition of Sadness and the Perceived Need for Social Support.” Evolutionary Psychology 11 (1): 148–58. https://doi.org/10.1177/147470491301100114.
Bani Salameh, Ayman. K., Malakeh. Z. Malak, Rasmieh. M. Al-Amer, Omar. S. H. Al Omari, Mamdouh El-Hneiti, and Loai. M. Abu Sharour. 2021. “Assessment of Temper Tantrums Behaviour Among Preschool Children in Jordan.” Journal of Pediatric Nursing 59 (July): e106–11. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.pedn.2021.02.008.
Barbarin, Oscar A. 1999. “Social Risks and Psychological Adjustment: A Comparison of African American and South African Children.” Child Development 70 (6): 1348–59.
Barnett, Melissa A., Lilly Shanahan, Min Deng, Mary E. Haskett, and Martha J. Cox. 2010. “Independent and Interactive Contributions of Parenting Behaviors and Beliefs in the Prediction of Early Childhood Behavior Problems.” Parenting 10 (1): 43–59. https://doi.org/10.1080/15295190903014604.
Barr, R. G. 1990. “The early crying paradox: A modest proposal.” Human Nature 1 (4): 355–89. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02734051.
Barr, R. G., M. Konner, R. Bakeman, and L. Adamson. 1991. “Crying in !Kung San infants: a test of the cultural specificity hypothesis.” Developmental Medicine and Child Neurology 33 (7): 601–10. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1469-8749.1991.tb14930.x.
Barry, Herbert, and Leonora M. Paxson. 1971. “Infancy and Early Childhood: Cross-Cultural Codes 2.” Ethnology 10 (4): 466–508. https://doi.org/10.2307/3773177.
Bateson, Patrick. 1994. “The Dynamics of Parent-Offspring Relationships in Mammals.” Trends in Ecology & Evolution 9 (10): 399–403. https://doi.org/10.1016/0169-5347(94)90066-3.
Beaulieu, David A., and Daphne Bugental. 2008. “Contingent Parental Investment: An Evolutionary Framework for Understanding Early Interaction Between Mothers and Children.” Evolution and Human Behavior 29 (4): 249–55. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2008.01.002.
Belden, Andy C., Nicole Renick Thomson, and Joan L. Luby. 2008. “Temper Tantrums in Healthy Versus Depressed and Disruptive Preschoolers: Defining Tantrum Behaviors Associated with Clinical Problems.” The Journal of Pediatrics 152 (1): 117–22. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpeds.2007.06.030.
Bergstrom, Carl T, and Theodore C Bergstrom. 1999. “Does Mother Nature Punish Rotten Kids?” Journal of Bioeconomics 1: 47–72.
Bhatia, Manjeet S, Naresh K Dhar, Puneet K Singhal, Vibha R Nigam, Satish C Malik, and DN Mullick. 1990. “Temper Tantrums: Prevalence and Etiology in a Non-Referral Outpatient Setting.” Clinical Pediatrics 29 (6): 311–15.
Blumberg, S J, K Bialostosky, W L Hamilton, and R R Briefel. 1999. “The Effectiveness of a Short Form of the Household Food Security Scale.” American Journal of Public Health 89 (8): 1231–34. https://doi.org/10.2105/AJPH.89.8.1231.
Blurton Jones, Nicholas G. 1993. “The Lives of Hunter-Gatherer Children: Effects of Parental Behavior and Parental Reproductive Strategy.” In Juvenile Primates: Life History, Development, and Behavior, edited by Michael E. Pereira and Lynn A. Fairbanks. New York, NY: The University of Chicago Press.
Bogart, Kathleen R., and David Matsumoto. 2010. “Living with Moebius syndrome: adjustment, social competence, and satisfaction with life.” The Cleft Palate-Craniofacial Journal 47 (2): 134–42. https://doi.org/10.1597/08-257_1.
Bogart, Kathleen R., Linda Tickle-Degnen, and Matthew S. Joffe. 2012. “Social interaction experiences of adults with Moebius Syndrome: a focus group.” Journal of Health Psychology 17 (8): 1212–22. https://doi.org/10.1177/1359105311432491.
Bossan, Benjamin, Peter Hammerstein, and Arnulf Koehncke. 2013. “We Were All Young Once: An Intragenomic Perspective on Parent-Offspring Conflict.” Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 280 (1754): 1–7. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2012.2637.
Bowlby, John. 1980. Attachment and Loss. Attachment and Loss. New York, NY: Basic Books.
Burchinal, Margaret, Debra Skinner, and J. Steven Reznick. 2010. “European American and African American Mothers’ Beliefs about Parenting and Disciplining Infants: A Mixed-Method Analysis.” Parenting 10 (2): 79–96. https://doi.org/10.1080/15295190903212604.
Burrows, Edwin G., and Melford E. Spiro. 1953. An atoll culture: ethnography of Ifaluk in the central Carolines. New Haven, CT: Human Relations Area Files. https://ehrafworldcultures.yale.edu/cultures/or21/documents/042.
Cano, Annmarie, and Amanda C de C Williams. 2010. “Social Interaction in Pain: Reinforcing Pain Behaviors or Building Intimacy?” Pain 149 (1): 9–11.
Caro, Shana M., Ashleigh S. Griffin, Camilla A. Hinde, and Stuart A. West. 2016. “Unpredictable Environments Lead to the Evolution of Parental Neglect in Birds.” Nature Communications 7 (1): 10985. https://doi.org/10.1038/ncomms10985.
Caro, Shana M., Stuart A. West, and Ashleigh S. Griffin. 2016. “Sibling Conflict and Dishonest Signaling in Birds.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 113 (48): 13803–8. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1606378113.
Chaudhary, Nikhil, Gul Deniz Salali, and Annie Swanepoel. 2024. “Sensitive Responsiveness and Multiple Caregiving Networks Among Mbendjele BaYaka Hunter-Gatherers: Potential Implications for Psychological Development and Well-Being.” Developmental Psychology 60 (3): 422–40. https://doi.org/10.1037/dev0001601.
Chisausky, Jacob, Carl Bergstrom, Kevin Zollman, and Graeme Ruxton. 2023. “Honest Signalling Made Simple.” https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.32942/X2H03D.
Clutton-Brock, T. H. 1991. The evolution of parental care. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Cornelius, Randolph R., and Susan M. Labott. 2001. “The Social Psychological Aspects of Crying.” In Adult Crying. New York, NY: Routledge.
Craig, Kenneth D. 2009. “The Social Communication Model of Pain.” Canadian Psychology/Psychologie Canadienne 50 (1): 22–23.
Cretser, Gary, William Lombardo, Barbara Lombardo, and Sharon Mathis. 1982. “Reactions to Men and Women Who Cry: A Study of Sex Differences in Perceived Societal Attitudes Versus Personal Attitudes.” Perceptual and Motor Skills 55 (2): 479–86. https://doi.org/10.2466/pms.1982.55.2.479.
Daly, Martin, and Margo Wilson. 1983. Sex, Evolution, and Behavior. Belmont: Wadsworth Publishing Company.
———. 1984. “A Sociobiological Analysis of Human Infanticide.” In Infanticide: Comparative and Evolutionary Perspectives, edited by Glenn Hausfater and Sarah Blaffer Hrdy, 487–502. New York: Aldine Press.
———. 1987. “The Darwinian psychology of discriminative parental solicitude.” Nebraska Symposium on Motivation 35: 91–144.
Daniels, Elizabeth, Barbara Mandleco, and Karlen E. Luthy. 2012. “Assessment, Management, and Prevention of Childhood Temper Tantrums.” Journal of the American Association of Nurse Practitioners 24 (10): 569. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1745-7599.2012.00755.x.
Darwin, Charles. 1872. The Expression of the Emotions in Man and Animals. London: John Murray.
Dávila-Cervantes, CA, and AM Pardo-Montaño. 2024. “The Trends of Interpersonal Violence Burden in Latin America, 1990 to 2019: Secondary Data Analysis from the Global Burden of Disease Study.” Public Health 228: 153–61.
Davis, Brittany Y. 2014. “Angling for Inclusion: Marine Conservation, Livelihoods, Local Knowledge, and Tourism on Utila, Honduras.” PhD thesis, Tucson, Arizona: University of Arizona.
Davison, Raziel J., and Michael Gurven. 2022. “The Importance of Elders: Extending Hamilton’s Force of Selection to Include Intergenerational Transfers.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 119 (28): e2200073119.
Davison, Raziel J., and Michael D Gurven. 2021. “Human Uniqueness? Life History Diversity Among Small-Scale Societies and Chimpanzees.” PLOS One 16 (2): e0239170.
Dawkins, Richard. 1976. The Selfish Gene. New York: Oxford University Press.
de Vries, M. W. 1987. “Cry Babies, Culture, and Catastrophe: Infant Temperament Among the Masai.” In Child Survival, edited by Nancy Scheper-Hughes, 165185. Dordrecht: D. Reidel Publishing Company. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-009-3393-4_9.
Dennis, Wayne. 1940. The Hopi Child. University of Virginia Institute for Research in the Social Sciences.
Du Bois, Cora Alice, Abram Kardiner, and Emil Oberholzer. 1944. The people of Alor: a social-psychological study of an East Indian Island. Minneapolis: Univ. of Minnesota Press. https://ehrafworldcultures.yale.edu/cultures/of05/documents/001.
Duncan, Lesley A, Mark Schaller, and Justin H Park. 2009. “Perceived Vulnerability to Disease: Development and Validation of a 15-Item Self-Report Instrument.” Personality and Individual Differences 47 (6): 541–46.
Emanuel, Aviv, and Eran Eldar. 2023. “Emotions as Computations.” Neuroscience & Biobehavioral Reviews 144 (January): 104977. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.neubiorev.2022.104977.
Emlen, Stephen T. 1995. “An Evolutionary Theory of the Family.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 92 (18): 8092–99. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.92.18.8092.
Emlen, Stephen T., and Peter H Wrege. 1992. “Parent-Offspring Conflict and the Recruitment of Helpers Among Bee-Eaters.” Nature 356 (6367): 331–33. https://doi.org/10.1038/356331a0.
Eshel, Ilan, and Marcus W Feldman. 1991. “The Handicap Principle in Parent-Offspring Conflict: Comparison of Optimality and Population-Genetic Analyses.” The American Naturalist 137 (2): 167–85.
Fischer, Ann M. 1950. The role of Trukese mother and its effect on child training. Scientific Investigation of Micronesia. https://ehrafworldcultures.yale.edu/cultures/or19/documents/027.
Flinn, M. 1989. “Household Composition and Female Reproductive Strategies in a Trinidadian Village.” In The Sociobiology of Sexual and Reproductive Strategies, edited by Anne Rasa, Christian Vogel, and Eckert Voland. London; New York: Chapman and Hall.
Fouts, Hillary N., Barry S. Hewlett, and Michael E. Lamb. 2005. “Parent-Offspring Weaning Conflicts Among the Bofi Farmers and Foragers of Central Africa.” Current Anthropology 46 (1): 29–50. https://doi.org/10.1086/425659.
Frankenhuis, Willem E., and Dorsa Amir. 2022. “What Is the Expected Human Childhood? Insights from Evolutionary Anthropology.” Development and Psychopathology 34 (2): 473–97. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0954579421001401.
Friedman, Jerome H., Trevor Hastie, and Rob Tibshirani. 2010. “Regularization Paths for Generalized Linear Models via Coordinate Descent.” Journal of Statistical Software 33 (February): 1–22. https://doi.org/10.18637/jss.v033.i01.
Frodi, Ann. 1985. “When Empathy Fails.” In Infant Crying: Theoretical and Research Perspectives, edited by Barry M. Lester and C. F. Zachariah Boukydis, 263–77. Boston, MA: Springer US. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4613-2381-5_12.
Fujiwara, Takeo, Ronald G. Barr, Rollin Brant, and Marilyn Barr. 2011. “Infant Distress at Five Weeks of Age and Caregiver Frustration.” The Journal of Pediatrics 159 (3): 425–430.e2. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpeds.2011.02.010.
Furlow, F. Bryant. 1997. “Human Neonatal Cry Quality as an Honest Signal of Fitness.” Evolution and Human Behavior 18 (3): 175–93. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1090-5138(97)00006-8.
Gaffney, Michael R., Kai H. Adams, Kristen L. Syme, and Edward H. Hagen. 2022. “Depression and Suicidality as Evolved Credible Signals of Need in Social Conflicts.” Evolution and Human Behavior 43 (3): 242–56. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2022.02.004.
Garcia, Angela R. 2018. “The Embodiment of Stress: Do Cortisol-Immune Interactions Moderate Social Influences on Health?” PhD thesis, Santa Barbara, CA: University of California, Santa Barbara. https://escholarship.org/uc/item/40j006mc.
Garcia, Angela R., Michael Gurven, and Aaron D. Blackwell. 2017. “A Matter of Perception: Perceived Socio-Economic Status and Cortisol on the Island of Utila, Honduras.” American Journal of Human Biology 29 (5): 1–17. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1002/ajhb.23031.
Gibson, M. A., and E. Gurmu. 2011. “Land Inheritance Establishes Sibling Competition for Marriage and Reproduction in Rural Ethiopia.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 108 (6): 2200–2204. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1010241108.
Glasberg, Rhoda, and Frances E Aboud. 1981. “A Developmental Perspective on the Study of Depression: Children’s Evaluative Reactions to Sadness.” Developmental Psychology 17 (2): 195.
———. 1982. “Keeping One’s Distance from Sadness: Children’s Self-Reports of Emotional Experience.” Developmental Psychology 18 (2): 287.
Godfray, H. C. J. 1991. “Signalling of Need by Offspring to Their Parents.” Nature 352 (6333): 328–30. https://doi.org/10.1038/352328a0.
———. 1995. “Evolutionary Theory of Parent—Offspring Conflict.” Nature 376 (6536): 133–38. https://doi.org/10.1038/376133a0.
Godfray, H. C. J., and R. A. Johnstone. 2000. “Begging and Bleating: The Evolution of Parent-Offspring Signalling.” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 355 (1403): 1581–91. https://doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2000.0719.
Godfray, H. C. J., and G. A. Parker. 1992. “Sibling Competition, Parent-Offspring Conflict and Clutch Size.” Animal Behaviour 43 (3): 473–90. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0003-3472(05)80106-X.
Goodall, Jane. 1986. The Chimpanzees of Gombe. Cambridge, Mass: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.
Goodenough, Florence Laura. 1931. “Anger in Young Children.” PhD thesis, Minneapolis, MN: The University of Minnesota.
Gracanin, Asmir, Lauren M. Bylsma, and Ad J. J. M. Vingerhoets. 2018. “Why Only Humans Shed Emotional Tears.” Human Nature 29 (2): 104–33. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12110-018-9312-8.
Gunderson, Christopher A., Alysha Baker, Alona D. Pence, and Leanne Ten Brinke. 2021. “Interpersonal Consequences of Deceptive Expressions of Sadness.” Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 49 (1): 97–109. https://doi.org/10.1177/01461672211059700.
Gurven, Michael, Wesley Allen-Arave, Kim Hill, and Magdalena Hurtado. 2000. “"It’s a Wonderful Life": Signaling Generosity Among the Ache of Paraguay.” Evolution and Human Behavior, 263–82.
Hadley, Craig, Tefera Belachew, David Lindstrom, and Fasil Tessema. 2011. “The Shape of Things to Come? Household Dependency Ratio and Adolescent Nutritional Status in Rural and Urban Ethiopia.” American Journal of Physical Anthropology 144 (4): 643–52. https://doi.org/10.1002/ajpa.21463.
Hagen, Edward H. 1999. “The Functions of Postpartum Depression.” Evolution and Human Behavior 20 (5): 325–59. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1090-5138(99)00016-1.
Hagen, Edward H., and H. Clark Barrett. 2009. “Cooperative Breeding and Adolescent Siblings: Evidence for the Ecological Constraints Model?” Current Anthropology 50 (5): 727–37. https://doi.org/10.1086/605328.
Hagen, Edward H., H. Clark Barrett, and Michael E. Price. 2006. “Do Human Parents Face a Quantity-Quality Tradeoff?: Evidence from a Shuar Community.” American Journal of Physical Anthropology 130 (3): 405–18. https://doi.org/10.1002/ajpa.20272.
Hagen, Edward H., and Kristen L. Syme. 2024. “Credible Sadness, Coercive Sadness: Depression as a Functional Response to Adversity and Strife.” In The Oxford Handbook of Evolution and the Emotions, edited by Laith Al-Shawaf and Todd K. Shackelford. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.
Hagen, Edward H., Paul J. Watson, and Peter Hammerstein. 2008. “Gestures of Despair and Hope: A View on Deliberate Self-Harm From Economics and Evolutionary Biology.” Biological Theory 3 (2): 123–38. https://doi.org/10.1162/biot.2008.3.2.123.
Harper, Alan B. 1986. “The Evolution of Begging: Sibling Competition and Parent-Offspring Conflict.” The American Naturalist 128 (1): 99–114.
Hasson, Oren. 2009. “Emotional Tears as Biological Signals.” Evolutionary Psychology 7 (3): 363–70.
Helfrecht, Courtney, and Courtney L. Meehan. 2016. “Sibling Effects on Nutritional Status: Intersections of Cooperation and Competition Across Development.” American Journal of Human Biology 28 (2): 159–70. https://doi.org/10.1002/ajhb.22763.
Henderson, Richard N. 1966. An outline of traditional Onitsha Ibo socialization. Ibadan: Institute of Education, University of Ibadan.
Hendriks, Michelle C. P., and Ad J. J. M. Vingerhoets. 2006. “Social Messages of Crying Faces: Their Influence on Anticipated Person Perception, Emotions and Behavioural Responses.” Cognition & Emotion 20 (6): 878–86. https://doi.org/10.1080/02699930500450218.
Hewlett, B. S., M. E. Lamb, D. Shannon, B. Leyendecker, and A. Schölmerich. 1998. “Culture and early infancy among central African foragers and farmers.” Developmental Psychology 34 (4): 653–61. https://doi.org/10.1037//0012-1649.34.4.653.
Hilger, M. Inez. 1957. Araucanian Child Life And Its Cultural Background. Washington: Smithsonian. http://ehrafworldcultures.yale.edu/document?id=sg04-010.
Hill, Sarah E, Gary W Boehm, and Marjorie L Prokosch. 2016. “Vulnerability to Disease as a Predictor of Faster Life History Strategies.” Adaptive Human Behavior and Physiology 2: 116–33.
Horwitz, Allan V., Jerome C. Wakefield, and Lorenzo Lorenzo-Luaces. 2017. “History of Depression.” In The Oxford Handbook of Mood Disorders, edited by Robert J. DeRubeis and Daniel R. Strunk, 11–23. New York, NY: Oxford University Press. https://www.oxfordhandbooks.com/view/10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199973965.001.0001/oxfordhb-9780199973965-e-2.
Howard, Cynthia R., Nancy Lanphear, Bruce P. Lanphear, Shirley Eberly, and Ruth A. Lawrence. 2006. “Parental Responses to Infant Crying and Colic: The Effect on Breastfeeding Duration.” Breastfeeding Medicine 1 (3): 146–55. https://doi.org/10.1089/bfm.2006.1.146.
Hrdy, Sarah Blaffer. 2009. Mothers and others: the evolutionary origins of mutual understanding. Cambridge, Mass: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.
Huth, Karoline BS, Jill de Ron, Anneke E Goudriaan, Judy Luigjes, Reza Mohammadi, Ruth J van Holst, Eric-Jan Wagenmakers, and Maarten Marsman. 2023. “Bayesian Analysis of Cross-Sectional Networks: A Tutorial in R and JASP.” Advances in Methods and Practices in Psychological Science 6 (4): 1–18.
Jesser, J. C. 1989. “Men and Crying.” Changing Men, no. 20: 12–15.
Johnson, Allen. 2003. Families of the Forest: The Matsigenka Indians of the Peruvian Amazon. Berkeley; Los Angeles, CA: Univ of California Press.
Kaplan, Hillard S., and Heather Dove. 1987. “Infant Development Among the Ache of Eastern Paraguay.” Developmental Psychology 23 (2): 190–98. https://doi.org/10.1037/0012-1649.23.2.190.
Kaplan, Hillard S., Paul L. Hooper, and Michael Gurven. 2009. “The Evolutionary and Ecological Roots of Human Social Organization.” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 364 (1533): 3289–99. https://doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2009.0115.
Kennedy, Patrick, and Andrew N Radford. 2021. “Kin Blackmail as a Coercive Route to Altruism.” The American Naturalist 197 (2): 266–73.
Koch, Ehud. 2003. “Reflections on a Study of Temper Tantrums in Older Children.” Psychoanalytic Psychology 20 (3): 456–71. https://doi.org/10.1037/0736-9735.20.3.456.
Konner, Melvin. 1974. “Aspects of the Developmental Ecology of a Foraging People.” In Ethological Studies of Child Behavior, edited by N. Blurton Jones, Revised ed. edition, 285–304. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Kramer, Karen L. 2018. “The Cooperative Economy of Food: Implications for Human Life History and Physiology.” Physiology & Behavior, The pace of life and feeding: Health implications, 193: 196–204. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.physbeh.2018.03.029.
Kramer, Karen L., and Amanda Veile. 2018. “Infant allocare in traditional societies.” Physiology & Behavior 193: 117–26. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.physbeh.2018.02.054.
Kruger, Ann Cale, and Melvin Konner. 2010. “Who Responds to Crying?” Human Nature 21 (3): 309–29. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12110-010-9095-z.
Kurth, Elisabeth, Holly Powell Kennedy, Elisabeth Spichiger, Irene Hösli, and Elisabeth Zemp Stutz. 2011. “Crying Babies, Tired Mothers: What Do We Know? A Systematic Review.” Midwifery 27 (2): 187–94. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.midw.2009.05.012.
Kushnick, Geoff. 2006. “Parent-Offspring Conflict Among the Karo of North Sumatra.” PhD thesis, Seattle, WA: University of Washington.
———. 2023. “Marriage: Parent-Offspring Conflict.” In Encyclopedia of Sexual Psychology and Behavior, edited by Todd K. Shackelford, 1–5. Cham: Springer International Publishing. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-08956-5_1416-1.
Lawson, David W., Alexandra Alvergne, and Mhairi A. Gibson. 2012. “The Life-History Trade-Off Between Fertility and Child Survival.” Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 279 (1748): 4755–64. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2012.1635.
Lawson, David W., and Monique Borgerhoff Mulder. 2016. “The Offspring Quantity–Quality Trade-Off and Human Fertility Variation.” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 371 (1692): 20150145.
Lawson, David W., and R. Mace. 2008. “Sibling Configuration and Childhood Growth in Contemporary British Families.” International Journal of Epidemiology 37 (6): 1408–21. https://doi.org/10.1093/ije/dyn116.
Leonard, Marty L, Andrew G Horn, Alison Gozna, and Satya Ramen. 2000. “Brood Size and Begging Intensity in Nestling Birds.” Behavioral Ecology 11 (2): 196–201.
Levenson, Robert W. 1999. “The Intrapersonal Functions of Emotion.” Cognition and Emotion 13 (5): 481–504. https://doi.org/10.1080/026999399379159.
Lin, Hung-Chu, and Robert McFatter. 2012. “Empathy and Distress: Two Distinct but Related Emotions in Response to Infant Crying.” Infant Behavior and Development 35 (4): 887–97. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.infbeh.2012.08.001.
Lowe, Edward D. 2003. “Identity, Activity, and the Well-Being of Adolescents and Youths: Lessons from Young People in a Micronesian Society.” Culture, Medicine and Psychiatry 27 (2): 187–219. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1024274024956.
Lummaa, V. 1998. “Why Cry? Adaptive Significance of Intensive Crying in Human Infants.” Evolution and Human Behavior 19 (3): 193–202. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1090-5138(98)00014-2.
Mace, Ruth. 1996. “Biased Parental Investment and Reproductive Success in Gabbra Pastoralists.” Behavioral Ecology and Sociobiology 38 (2): 75–81. https://doi.org/10.1007/s002650050219.
Macfarlane, Jean Walker, Lucile Allen, and Marjorie P. Honzik. 1954. A Developmental Study of the Behavior Problems of Normal Children Between 21 Months and 14 Years. Berkeley, CA: Univ of California Press.
Maute, Monique, and Sonja Perren. 2018. “Ignoring Children’s Bedtime Crying: The Power of Western-Oriented Beliefs.” Infant Mental Health Journal 39 (2): 220–30. https://doi.org/10.1002/imhj.21700.
Maynard Smith, J., and D. G. C. Harper. 1995. “Animal Signals: Models and Terminology.” Journal of Theoretical Biology 177 (3): 305–11. https://doi.org/10.1006/jtbi.1995.0248.
Maynard-Smith, John, and David Harper. 2004. Animal Signals. New York: Oxford University Press.
McGuire, Jacqueline Barnes. 1997. “The Reliability and Validity of a Questionnaire Describing Neighborhood Characteristics Relevant to Families and Young Children Living in Urban Areas.” Journal of Community Psychology 25 (6): 551–66.
Meehan, Courtney L. 2009. “Maternal Time Allocation in Two Cooperative Childrearing Societies.” Human Nature 20 (4): 375–93. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12110-009-9076-2.
Meehan, Courtney L., Edward H. Hagen, and Barry S. Hewlett. 2017. “Persistence of Infant Care Patterns Among Aka Foragers.” In Hunter-Gatherers in a Changing World, edited by Victoria Reyes-García and Aili Pyhälä, 213–31. Switzerland: Springer International Publishing. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-42271-8_12.
Mehr, Samuel A., Max M. Krasnow, Gregory A. Bryant, and Edward H. Hagen. 2021. “Origins of Music in Credible Signaling.” Behavioral and Brain Sciences 44 (January): e60. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0140525X20000345.
Meij, J. J., D. Van Bodegom, J. B. Ziem, J. Amankwa, A. M. Polderman, T. B. L. Kirkwood, A. J. M. De Craen, B. J. Zwaan, and R. G. J. Westendorp. 2009. “Quality-Quantity Trade-Off of Human Offspring Under Adverse Environmental Conditions.” Journal of Evolutionary Biology 22 (5): 1014–23. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1420-9101.2009.01713.x.
Mock, Douglas W., Matthew B. Dugas, and Stephanie A. Strickler. 2011. “Honest Begging: Expanding from Signal of Need.” Behavioral Ecology 22 (5): 909–17. https://doi.org/10.1093/beheco/arr091.
Mock, Douglas W., and Geoffrey A. Parker. 1997. The Evolution of Sibling Rivalry. Oxford Series in Ecology and Evolution. Oxford; New York: Oxford University Press.
Müller, Fernanda. 2021. I Cry, Therefore I Am: An Anthropological Study of Babies’ Interactions.” Learning, Culture and Social Interaction 31 (December): 100562. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.lcsi.2021.100562.
Murube, Juan. 2009. “Basal, reflex, and psycho-emotional tears.” The Ocular Surface 7 (2): 60–66. https://doi.org/10.1016/s1542-0124(12)70296-3.
Myers, Fred R. 1988. “The Logic and Meaning of Anger Among Pintupi Aborigines.” Man, 589–610.
Nesse, Randolph M. 1990. “Evolutionary Explanations of Emotions.” Human Nature 1 (3): 261–89. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02733986.
———. 2019. Good Reasons for Bad Feelings: Insights from the Frontier of Evolutionary Psychiatry. New York, NY: Penguin.
Nesse, Randolph M., and Phoebe C. Ellsworth. 2009. “Evolution, emotions, and emotional disorders.” The American Psychologist 64 (2): 129–39. https://doi.org/10.1037/a0013503.
Nettle, Daniel. 2009. “An Evolutionary Model of Low Mood States.” Journal of Theoretical Biology 257 (1): 100–103. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jtbi.2008.10.033.
Neuenschwander, Samuel, Martin WG Brinkhof, Mathias Kölliker, and Heinz Richner. 2003. “Brood Size, Sibling Competition, and the Cost of Begging in Great Tits (Parus Major).” Behavioral Ecology 14 (4): 457–62.
Nock, Matthew K. 2008. “Actions Speak Louder Than Words: An Elaborated Theoretical Model of the Social Functions of Self-Injury and Other Harmful Behaviors.” Applied and Preventive Psychology 12 (4): 159–68.
Österman, Karin, and Kaj Björkqvist. 2010. “A Cross-Sectional Study of Onset, Cessation, Frequency, and Duration of Children’s Temper Tantrums in a Nonclinical Sample.” Psychological Reports 106 (2): 448–54.
Potegal, Michael. 2019. “On Being, Mad, Sad, and Very Young.” In Irritability in Pediatric Psychopathology, edited by Amy Krain Roy, Melissa A. Brotman, and Ellen Leibenluft. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.
Potegal, Michael, and Richard J. Davidson. 2003. “Temper Tantrums in Young Children: 1. Behavioral Composition:” Journal of Developmental & Behavioral Pediatrics 24 (3): 140–47. https://doi.org/10.1097/00004703-200306000-00002.
Preuschoft, Signe, and Carel van Schaik. 2000. “Dominance and Communication: Conflict Management in Various Social Settings.” In Natural Conflict Resolution, edited by Filippo Aurelli and Franz de Waal, 77–105. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Rao, Madu, Elliott M Blass, Marie M Brignol, Lauren Marino, and Leonard Glass. 1997. “Reduced Heat Loss Following Sucrose Ingestion in Premature and Normal Human Newborns.” Early Human Development 48 (1): 109–16. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0378-3782(96)01847-6.
Reed, Lawrence Ian, and Peter DeScioli. 2017. “The Communicative Function of Sad Facial Expressions.” Evolutionary Psychology 15 (1): 1–9. https://doi.org/10.1177/1474704917700418.
Reijneveld, Sijmen A., Marcel F. van der Wal, Emily Brugman, Remy A. Hira Sing, and S. Pauline Verloove-Vanhorick. 2004. “Infant Crying and Abuse.” The Lancet 364 (9442): 1340–42. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0140-6736(04)17191-2.
Rosenberg, Karen R. 2021. “The Evolution of Human Infancy: Why It Helps to Be Helpless.” Annual Review of Anthropology 50: 423–40. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-anthro-111819-105454.
Rottenberg, Jonathan, and Ad J. J. M. Vingerhoets. 2012. “Crying: Call for a Lifespan Approach.” Social and Personality Psychology Compass 6 (3): 217–27.
Salmon, Catherine A, and Jessica A Hehman. 2014. “The Evolutionary Psychology of Sibling Conflict and Siblicide.” In The Evolution of Violence, edited by Todd K Shackleford and Ronald D Hansen. Evolutionary Psychology. New York, NY: Springer.
Schaller, George B. 1964. “Breeding Behavior of the White Pelican at Yellowstone Lake, Wyoming.” The Condor 66 (1): 3–23. https://doi.org/10.2307/1365232.
Schiavenato, Martin, and Kenneth D Craig. 2010. “Pain Assessment as a Social Transaction: Beyond the ‘Gold Standard’.” The Clinical Journal of Pain 26 (8): 667–76.
Schmitt, Barton D. 1987. “Seven Deadly Sins of Childhood: Advising Parents about Difficult Developmental Phases.” Child Abuse & Neglect 11 (3): 421–32. https://doi.org/10.1016/0145-2134(87)90015-9.
Schniter, Eric, Daniel K Cummings, Paul L Hooper, Jonathan Stieglitz, Benjamin C Trumble, Hillard S Kaplan, and Michael D Gurven. 2023. “Who Helps Tsimane Youth?” Hunter Gatherer Research 9 (3-4): 287–322.
Schniter, Eric, Michael Gurven, Hillard S. Kaplan, Nathaniel T. Wilcox, and Paul L. Hooper. 2015. “Skill Ontogeny Among Tsimane Forager-Horticulturalists.” American Journal of Physical Anthropology 158 (1): 3–18. https://doi.org/10.1002/ajpa.22757.
Sear, R, and R Mace. 2008. “Who Keeps Children Alive? A Review of the Effects of Kin on Child Survival.” Evolution and Human Behavior 29 (1): 1–18. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2007.10.001.
Setchell, Joanna M., and E. Jean Wickings. 2005. “Dominance, Status Signals and Coloration in Male Mandrills (Mandrillus Sphinx).” Ethology 111 (1): 25–50. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1439-0310.2004.01054.x.
Shostak, Marjorie. 1981. Nisa, the life and words of a!Kung woman. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press.
Smith, Craig A., and Richard S. Lazarus. 1993. “Appraisal Components, Core Relational Themes, and the Emotions.” Cognition and Emotion 7 (3-4): 233–69. https://doi.org/10.1080/02699939308409189.
Soltis, Joseph. 2004. “The Signal Functions of Early Infant Crying.” Behavioral and Brain Sciences 27 (August): 443–90. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0140525X0400010X.
Spence, Michael. 1973. “Job Market Signaling.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 87 (3): 355–74. https://doi.org/10.2307/1882010.
Stonich, Susan C. 2000. The Other Side of Paradise: Tourism, Conservation, and Development in the Bay Islands. New York, NY: Cognizant Communication Corp.
Strassmann, Beverly I. 2011. “Cooperation and Competition in a Cliff-Dwelling People.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 108 (Supplement 2): 10894–901. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1100306108.
Syme, Kristen L., and Daniel Balliet. 2024. “Psychological Adaptations for Fitness Interdependence Underlie Cooperation Across Human Ecologies.” Psychological Review.
Syme, Kristen L., Zachary H. Garfield, and Edward H. Hagen. 2016. “Testing the Bargaining Vs. Inclusive Fitness Models of Suicidal Behavior Against the Ethnographic Record.” Evolution and Human Behavior 37 (3): 179–92. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2015.10.005.
Syme, Kristen L., and Edward H. Hagen. 2023. “Bargaining and Interdependence: Common Parent-Offspring Conflict Resolution Strategies Among Chon Chuuk and Their Implications for Suicidal Behavior.” American Anthropologist 125 (2): 262–82. https://doi.org/10.1111/aman.13821.
Sznycer, Daniel, Asmir Gracanin, and Debra Lieberman. 2023. “Emotional Tears: What They Are and How They Work.” https://doi.org/10.31234/osf.io/fht2g.
Thornhill, Randy, and Nancy Wilmsen Thornhill. 1989. “The Evolution of Psychological Pain.” In Sociobiology and the Social Sciences, edited by R. W. Bell and N. J. Bell, 73–103. Lubbock, TX: Texas Tech University Press.
Thureen, P. J., R. E. Phillips, K. A. Baron, M. P. DeMarie, and W. W. Hay. 1998. “Direct measurement of the energy expenditure of physical activity in preterm infants.” Journal of Applied Physiology 85 (1): 223–30. https://doi.org/10.1152/jappl.1998.85.1.223.
Tomasello, Michael, Alicia P. Melis, Claudio Tennie, Emily Wyman, and Esther Herrmann. 2012. “Two Key Steps in the Evolution of Human Cooperation: The Interdependence Hypothesis.” Current Anthropology 53 (6): 673–92. https://doi.org/10.1086/668207.
Trimmer, Pete C, Andrew D Higginson, Tim W Fawcett, John M McNamara, and Alasdair I Houston. 2015. “Adaptive Learning Can Result in a Failure to Profit from Good Conditions: Implications for Understanding Depression.” Evolution, Medicine, and Public Health 2015 (1): 123–35.
Trivers, Robert L. 1974. “Parent-Offspring Conflict.” American Zoologist 14 (1): 249–64.
Tronick, Edward Z., Gilda A. Morelli, and Steve Winn. 1987. “Multiple Caretaking of Efe (Pygmy) Infants.” American Anthropologist 89 (1): 96–106. https://www.jstor.org/stable/678750.
Tukey, John W. 1977. Exploratory Data Analysis. Reading, MA: Pearson.
Turke, P. 1988. “Helpers at the Nest: Childcare Networks on Ifaluk.” In Human Reproductive Behavior, edited by L. Betzig and Monique Borgerhoff Mulder. Cambridge: Cambridge University.
Van den akker, Alithe L., Peter Hoffenaar, and Geertjan Overbeek. 2022. “Temper Tantrums in Toddlers and Preschoolers: Longitudinal Associations with Adjustment Problems.” Journal of Developmental & Behavioral Pediatrics 43 (7): 409. https://doi.org/10.1097/DBP.0000000000001071.
Vermillet, Arnault-Quentin, Katrine Tølbøll, Samouil Litsis Mizan, Joshua C Skewes, and Christine E Parsons. 2022. “Crying in the First 12 Months of Life: A Systematic Review and Meta-Analysis of Cross-Country Parent-Reported Data and Modeling of the ‘Cry Curve’.” Child Development 93 (4): 1201–22.
Vigil, Jacob M, and Chance Strenth. 2014. “No Pain, No Social Gains: A Social-Signaling Perspective of Human Pain Behaviors.” World Journal of Anesthesiology 3 (1): 18–30.
Vingerhoets, Ad J. J. M. 2013. Why Only Humans Weep: Unravelling the Mysteries of Tears. Oxford: Oxford University Press. https://doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780198570240.001.0001.
Vingerhoets, Ad J. J. M., Niels van de Ven, and Yvonne van der Velden. 2016. “The Social Impact of Emotional Tears.” Motivation and Emotion 40 (3): 455–63. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11031-016-9543-0.
Ward, Barbara E. 1970. “Temper Tantrums in Kau Sai: Some Speculations Upon Their Effects.” In Socialization, edited by Philip Mayer, 109–25. Routledge.
Weisner, Thomas S., and Ronald Gallimore. 1977. “My Brother’s Keeper: Child and Sibling Caretaking.” Current Anthropology 18 (2): 169–90. https://doi.org/10.1086/201883.
Wells, Jonathan C. K. 2003. “Parent-Offspring Conflict Theory, Signaling of Need, and Weight Gain in Early Life.” The Quarterly Review of Biology 78 (2): 169–202. https://doi.org/10.1086/374952.
Wurm, Michael J., Paul J. Rathouz, and Bret M. Hanlon. 2021. “Regularized Ordinal Regression and the ordinalNet R Package.” Journal of Statistical Software 99 (6): 1–42. https://doi.org/10.18637/jss.v099.i06.
Zahavi, Amotz. 1975. “Mate Selection—a Selection for a Handicap.” Journal of Theoretical Biology 53 (1): 205–14. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-5193(75)90111-3.
———. 1977. “Reliability in Communication Systems and the Evolution of Altruism.” In Evolutionary Ecology, edited by Bernard Stonehouse and Christopher Perrins, 253–59. London: Macmillan Education UK. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-05226-4_21.
———. 1993. “The Fallacy of Conventional Signalling.” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 340 (1292): 227–30.
Zeevenhooven, Judith, Pamela D. Browne, Monique P. L’Hoir, Carolina de Weerth, and Marc A. Benninga. 2018. “Infant Colic: Mechanisms and Management.” Nature Reviews Gastroenterology & Hepatology 15 (8): 479–96. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41575-018-0008-7.
Zeifman, Debra M. 2013. “Crying over the Lifespan.” In Why Only Humans Weep. Oxford: Oxford Academic.
Zeifman, Debra M., and Ian St James-Roberts. 2017. “Parenting the Crying Infant.” Current Opinion in Psychology 15 (June): 149–54. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.copsyc.2017.02.009.
Zeman, Janice, and Judy Garber. 1996. “Display Rules for Anger, Sadness, and Pain: It Depends on Who Is Watching.” Child Development 67 (3): 957–73.
Zickfeld, Janis, Beate Seibt, Lili Lazarevic, Iris Zezelj, and Ad J. J. M. Vingerhoets. 2020. “A Model of Positive Tears.” https://doi.org/10.31234/osf.io/sf7pe.
Zou, Hui, and Trevor Hastie. 2005. “Regularization and Variable Selection via the Elastic Net.” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society Series B: Statistical Methodology 67 (2): 301–20.

Footnotes

  1. Even when a mechanism is needed to ensure honesty, it is possible for signal cost to be zero at equilibrium because it is the potential cost of deceptive signaling, not honest signaling, that ensures honesty (Chisausky et al. 2023).↩︎

  2. Because we wanted a relatedness value for all ego children, including those without siblings, this measure included the focal child (r=1) in calculations of average child relatedness within households.↩︎